Title:   Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

Subject:  

Author:   Arnold Toynbee

Keywords:  

Creator:  

PDF Version:   1.2



Contents:

Page No 1

Page No 2

Page No 3

Page No 4

Page No 5

Page No 6

Page No 7

Page No 8

Page No 9

Page No 10

Page No 11

Page No 12

Page No 13

Page No 14

Page No 15

Page No 16

Page No 17

Page No 18

Page No 19

Page No 20

Page No 21

Page No 22

Page No 23

Page No 24

Page No 25

Page No 26

Page No 27

Page No 28

Page No 29

Page No 30

Page No 31

Page No 32

Page No 33

Page No 34

Page No 35

Page No 36

Page No 37

Page No 38

Page No 39

Page No 40

Page No 41

Page No 42

Page No 43

Page No 44

Page No 45

Page No 46

Page No 47

Page No 48

Page No 49

Page No 50

Page No 51

Page No 52

Page No 53

Page No 54

Page No 55

Page No 56

Page No 57

Page No 58

Bookmarks





Page No 1


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

Arnold Toynbee



Top




Page No 2


Table of Contents

Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England.........................................................................................1

Arnold Toynbee.......................................................................................................................................1

I Introductory...........................................................................................................................................1

II. England in 1760..................................................................................................................................3

III England in 1760..................................................................................................................................7

IV England in 1760 ................................................................................................................................10

V. England in 1760................................................................................................................................15

VI. England in 1760 ...............................................................................................................................19

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith .......................................................................................21

VIII. The Chief Features of the Revolution ...........................................................................................27

IX. The Growth of Pauperism ................................................................................................................31

X. Malthus and the Law of Population..................................................................................................36

XI. The WageFund Theory ..................................................................................................................40

XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent .....................................................................................................45

XIII. Two Theories of Economic Progress ............................................................................................50

XIV. The Future of the Working Classes..............................................................................................52


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

i



Top




Page No 3


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

Arnold Toynbee

I Introductory 

II. England in 1760 

III England in 1760 

IV England in 1760 

V. England in 1760 

VI. England in 1760 

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith 

VIII. The Chief Features of the Revolution 

IX. The Growth of Pauperism 

X. Malthus and the Law of Population 

XI. The WageFund Theory 

XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent 

XIII. Two Theories of Economic Progress 

XIV. The Future of the Working Classes  

I Introductory

The subject of these lectures is the industrial and Agrarian  Revolution at the end of the eighteenth and

beginning of the  nineteenth centuries. The course is divided into three parts. The  first deals with Adam Smith

and the England of his time. It will  describe England on the eve of the Industrial Revolution, and the  system

of regulation and protection of industry as it existed in  1760. It will give also an outline of Adam Smith's

hook, its aims  and  character, and especially his theory of free trade. The  second part  will group itself round

the work of Malthus, who  dealt not so much  with the causes of wealth as with the causes of  poverty, with the

distribution of wealth rather than with its  production. It will  describe England in the midst of the  industrial

Revolution, and will  inquire into the problem of  pauperism and the subjects connected with  it. The third part

will  he associated with the name of Ricardo, and  will deal with  England at the time of the Peace. It will

discuss the  doctrine of  rent and wages together with certain theories of economic  progress, and will cover the

questions of currency, so much  agitated  at that period, and the history of the commercial and  financial

changes which followed the Peace. 

I have chosen the subject because it was in this period that  modern Political Economy took its rise. It has

been a weakness of  the  science, as pursued in England, that it has been too much  dissociated  from History.

Adam Smith and Malthus, indeed, had  historical minds;  but the form of modern textbooks is due to  Ricardo,

whose mind was  entirely unhistorical. Yet there is a  double advantage in combining  the two studies. In the

first place  Political Economy is better  understood by this means. Abstract  propositions are seen in a new  light

when studied in relation to  the facts which were before the  writer at the time when he  formulated them. So

regarded they are at  once more vivid and less  likely to mislead. Ricardo becomes painfully  interesting when

he  read the history of his time. And, in the second  place, History  also is better understood when studied in

Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England 1



Top




Page No 4


connection  with  Political Economy; for the latter not only teaches us in reading  History to look out for the

right kind of facts, but enables us  to  explain many phenomena like those attending the introduction  of

enclosures and machinery, or the effects of different systems  of  currency, which without its assistance would

remain  unintelligible.  The careful deductive reasoning, too, which  Political Economy teaches  is of great

importance to the  historian, and the habits of mind  acquired from it are even more  valuable than the

knowledge of  principles which it gives,  especially to students of facts, who might  otherwise be  overwhelmed

by the mass of their materials. 

Of late years, however, there has been a steady sustained  attack  upon the abstract Deductive Method of

Political Economy  pursued by  Ricardo and Mill, and an attempt to set up historical  investigation in  its place

as the only true method of economic  inquiry. This attack  rests on a misconception of the function of  the

Deductive Method. The  best exposition of the place of  Abstract Political Economy is to be  found in Bagehot's

Economic  Studies. Bagehot points out that this  abstract science holds good  only upon certain assumptions,

but though  the assumptions are  often not entirely correct, the results may yet be  approximately  true. Thus the

economists, firstly, regard only one part  of man's  nature, and treat him simply as a moneymaking animal;

secondly,  they disregard the influence of custom, and only take  account of  competition. Certain laws are laid

down under these  assumptions;  as, for instance, that the rate of wages always tends to  an  equality, the

permanent difference obtaining in various  employments being only sufficient to balance the favourable or

unfavourable circumstances attending each of thema law which is  only  true after a certain stage of

civilisation and in so far as  the  acquisition of wealth is the sole object of men. Such  hypothetical  laws, though

leading only to rough conclusions, are  yet useful in  giving us a point of view from which to observe and

indicate the  existence of strong overmastering tendencies.  Advocates of the  Historical Method, like Mr

Cliffe Leslie,  therefore, go too far when  they condemn the Deductive Method as  radically false. There is no

real  opposition between the two. The  apparent opposition is due to a wrong  use of deduction; to a  neglect on

the part of those employing it to  examine closely  their assumptions and to bring their conclusions to  the test

of  fact; to arguments based on premises which are not only  not  verified but absolutely untrue (as in the

wagefund theory); and  generally to the failure to combine induction with deduction. But  this misuse of the

method does not imply any radical faultiness  in  it. The right method in any particular case must be largely

determined  by the nature of the problem. Neither is it fair to  make abstract  Political Economy responsible for

the confusion in  many minds between  its laws and the precepts which are based on  them. It is a pure  science,

and its end is knowledge. But the  Political Economy of the  press and the platform is a practical  science, that

is, a body of  rules and maxims to guide conduct.  Journalists and members of  Parliament confound the laws of

the  pure science with the maxims of  the practical science. It was  thus that Mr Gladstone in the Land Act

controversy of 1881 was  constantly accused of violating the laws of  Political Economy. It  was impossible for

Mr Gladstone to do any such  thing. The laws of  Political Economy can no more be violated than  those of

physical  science. What the journalists meant was that he had  departed from  a great economic precept  that

which recommends freedom  of  contract. 

The Historical Method pursues a different line of  investigation.  It examines the actual causes of economic

development and considers  the influence of institutions, such as  the medieval guilds, our  present landlaws,

or the political  constitution of any given country,  in determining the  distribution of wealth. Without the aid of

the  Historical Method  it would be impossible, for instance, to understand  why onehalf  of the land in the

United Kingdom is owned by 2512  persons. 

And not only does it investigate the stages of economic  development in a given country, but it compares them

with those  which  have obtained in other countries and times, and seeks by  such  comparison to discover laws

of universal application. Take,  as an  instance of the discoveries of this Comparative Political  Economy, the

tendency which Sir H. Maine and M. de Laveleye have  pointed out to  pass from collective to individual

ownership of  land. This is a law  which is true of nearly all civilised  countries. We must be careful,  however,

not to generalise too  hastily in these matters. A clever  pamphlet lately published in  Dublin appeals to another

generalisation  of Sir H. Maine   'Maine's Law,' as it is denominated  in  condemnation of recent  legislation.


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England 2



Top




Page No 5


'Sir H. Maine,' says the writer,  'in his Ancient Law  has remarked that the movement of all progressive

societies has  hitherto been a movement from status to contract. The  demand of  this agitation is that Ireland

should be legislatively  declared a  retrograde society, and that the social movement should be  from  contract

back again to status.' 'is it expedient,' asks another,  'to reform our laws so as to assimilate them to those in use

among  nations of an inferior social development?' A deeper study  of existing  civilisation in England, and of

other civilisations,  past and present,  would have shown that the step was not a  retrograde one  that whilst  the

sphere of contract has been  widening, it has been also narrowing,  and that such a condition  of things as we

see in Ireland has never  existed anywhere else  without deep social misery, outrage, and  disturbance. Custom

or  law or public opinion, or all three, have  intervened in the past,  and will intervene in the future. It is true

that there is a  movement from status to contract; yet if we look  closely, we find  that the State has over and

over again had to  interfere to  restrict the power of individuals in which this movement  results.  The real course

of development has been first from status to  contract, then from contract to a new kind of status determined

by  the law or, in other words, from unregulated to regulated  contract.  The Historical Method is also of value

because it makes  us see where  economic laws and precepts are relative. The old  economists were wont  to

speak as if these laws and precepts were  universal. Free trade, for  instance, is a sound policy, no doubt,  for

England, and for all  nations at a certain stage of  development; but it is open to any one  to say that free trade is

only good under certain conditions. No  English economist, it is  true, has dared to say this. Mr Jevons, to  take

an example, would  admit restrictions only for considerations of  the most paramount  importance.6 But it is an

unjustifiable prejudgment  of the  question to lay down that this policy must be wise at all times  and places. I

do not mean to assert, however, that there are not  some  laws which are universally true, such as the law of

diminishing  returns. 

This discussion about method may seem barren, but it is not  really  so. Take such a question as the functions

of the State. Mr  Senior  spent much time in attempting to discover an universal  formula which  should define

their proper limit all the world  over. Such an attempt  must be abandoned. The proper limits of  Government

interference are  relative to the nature of each  particular state and the stage of its  civilisation. It is a  matter of

great importance at the present day  for us to discover  what these limits are in our own case, for  administration

bids  fair to claim a large share of our attention in  the future. It  would be well if, in studying the past, we could

always  bear in  mind the problems of the present, and go to that past to seek  large views of what is of lasting

importance to the human race.  It is  an old complaint that histories leave out of sight those  vital  questions

which are connected with the condition of the  people. The  French Revolution has indeed profoundly

modified our  views of history,  but much still remains to be done in that  direction. If I could  persuade some of

those present to study  Economic History, to follow  out the impulse originally given by  Malthus to the study

of the  history of the mass of the people, I  should be indeed glad. Party  historians go to the past for party

purposes; they seek to read into  the past the controversies of  the present. You must pursue facts for  their own

sake, but  penetrated with a vivid sense of the problems of  your own time.  This is not a principle of

perversion, but a principle  of  selection. You must have some principle of selection, and you  could not have a

better one than to pay special attention to the  history of the social problems which are agitating the world

now,  for  you may be sure that they are problems not of temporary but  of lasting  importance. 

II. England in 1760

Population 

Previously to 1760 the old industrial system obtained in  England;  none of the great mechanical inventions

had been  introduced; the  agrarian changes were still in the future. It is  this industrial  England which we have

to contrast with the  industrial England of  today. For determining the population of  the time we have no

accurate  materials. There are no official  returns before 1801. A census had  been proposed in 1753, but

rejected as 'subversive of the last remains  of English liberty.'  In this absence of trustworthy data all sorts of

wild estimates  were formed. During the American War a great  controversy raged on  this subject. Dr Price, an


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

II. England in 1760 3



Top




Page No 6


advocate of the  Sinking Fund,  maintained that population had in the interval between  1690 and  1777 declined

from 6,596,075 to 4,763,670. On the other hand,  Mr  Howlett, Vicar of Dunmow, in Essex, estimated the

population in  1780 at 8,691,000, and Arthur Young, in 1770, at 8,500,000 on the  lowest estimate. These,

however, are the extremes in either  direction. The computations now most generally accepted are those  made

by Mr Finlaison (Actuary to the National Debt Office), and  published in the Preface to the Census Returns of

1831. These are  based on an examination of the registers of baptisms and burials  of  the eighteenth century.

But the data are deficient in three  respects:  because the number of people existing at the date when  the

computation  begins is a matter of conjecture; because in some  parishes there were  no registers; and because

the registration,  being voluntary, was  incomplete. Mr Finlaison, however, is stated  to have subjected his

materials to 'every test suggested by the  present comparatively  advanced state of physical and statistical

science.' 

Now according to Mr Finlaison, the population of England and  Wales  was, in 1700, 5,134,516, in 1750,

6,039,684, an increase of  not quite  a million, or between 17 and 18 per cent. In the first  half of the  century. in

1801 the population of England and Wales  was 9,187,176,  showing an increase of three millions, or more

than 52 per cent. In  the second half.8 The difference in the rate  of increase is  significant of the great contrast

presented by the  two periods. In the  former, England, though rapidly increasing in  wealth owing to her

extended commercial relations, yet retained  her old industrial  organisation; the latter is the age of  transition to

the modern  industrial system, and to improved  methods of agriculture. 

The next point to consider is the distribution of population.  A  great difference will be found here between the

state of things  at the  beginning of the eighteenth century, or in Adam Smith's  time, and that  prevailing now.

Every one remembers Macaulay's  famous description in  the beginning of his history of the  desolate condition

of the northern  counties. His picture is borne  out by Defoe, who, in his Tour through  the Whole Island

(1725),  remarks: 'The country south of Trent is by  far the largest, as  well as the richest and most populous,'

though the  great cities  were rivalled by those of the north. if we consider as  the  counties north of Trent

Northumberland, Durham, Yorkshire,  Cumberland, Westmoreland, Lancashire, Cheshire, Derbyshire,

Nottinghamshire, and Staffordshire (about onethird of the total  area  of England), we shall find on

examination that in 1700 they  contained  about onefourth of the population,10 and in 1750 less  than

onethird,  while in 1881, they contained more than  twofifths; or, taking only  the six northern counties, we

find  that in 1700 their population was  under onefifth of that of all  England, in 1750 it was about  onefifth,

in 1881 it was all but  onethird. 

In 1700 the most thickly peopled counties (excluding the  metropolitan counties of Middlesex and Surrey)

were  Gloucestershire,  Somerset, and Wilts, the manufacturing districts  of the west;  Worcestershire and

Northamptonshire, the seats of  the Midland  manufactures; and the agriculture counties of Herts  and Bucks 

all of  them being south of the Trent. Between 1700  and 1750 the greatest  increase of population took place in

the  following counties: 

Lancashire increased from 166,200 to 297,400, or 78 per cent.

Warwickshire " 96,000 " 140,000, " 45 "

The West Riding " 236,700 " 361,500, " 52 "

of Yorkshire

Durham  " 95,000 " 135,000, " 41 "

Staffordshire " 117,200 " 160,000, " 36 "

Gloucestershire  " 155,200 " 207,800, " 34 "

Cornwall, Kent, Berks, Herts, Worcestershire, Salop, Cheshire,  Northumberland, Cumberland, and

Westmoreland each increased  upwards  of 20 per cent. 

The change in the distribution of population between the  beginning  of the eighteenth century and Adam

Smith's time, and  again between his  time and our own, may be further illustrated by  the following table.  The


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

II. England in 1760 4



Top




Page No 7


twelve most densely populated counties  and their density to the  square mile were: 

1700 1750 1881

Middlesex 2221 Middlesex 2283 Middlesex 10,387

Surrey 207 Surrey 276 Surrey 1,919

Gloucester 123 Warwick 159 Lancashire 1,813

Northampton 121 Gloucester 157 Durham 891

Somerset 119 Lancashire 156 Stafford 862

Worcester 119 Worcester 148 Warwick 825

Herts 115 Herts 141 West Riding 815

Wilts 113 Stafford 140 Kent 600

Bucks 110 Durham 138 Cheshire 582

Rutland 110 Somerset 137 Worcester 515

Warwick 109 West Riding 135 Nottingham 475

Oxford 107 Berks 131 Gloucester 455

The most suggestive fact in the period between 1700 and 1750  is  the great increase in the Lancashire and the

West Riding, the  seats of  the cotton and coarse woollen manufactures.  Staffordshire and  Warwickshire, with

their potteries and  hardware, had also largely  grown. So had the two northern  counties of Durham and

Northumberland,  with their coalfields. The  West of England woollen districts of  Somerset, and Wilts, on the

other hand, though they had grown also,  showed nothing like so  great an increase. The population of the

eastern counties  Norfolk, Suffolk, and Essex, had increased very  little; though  Norwich was still a large

manufacturing town, and there  were many  smaller towns engaged in the woollen trade scattered  throughout

Norfolk and Suffolk. Among the few agricultural counties  which  showed a decided increase during this

period was Kent, the best  farmed county in England at that time. 

If we turn to the principal towns we shall find in many of  them an  extraordinary growth between the end of

the seventeenth  century and  the time of Adam Smith. While the population of  Norwich had only  increased,

according to the best authority, by  about onethird, and  that of Worcester by onehalf, the  population of

Sheffield had  increased sevenfold, that of  Liverpool tenfold, of Manchester  fivefold, of Birmingham

sevenfold, of Bristol more than threefold.  The latter was still  the second city in the kingdom. Newcastle

(including Gateshead  and North and South Shields) numbered 40,000  people. 

The following are the estimates of population for 1685, 1760,  and  1881 in twelve great provincial towns: 

             1685a          c. 1760                1881g

Liverpool    4,000          40,000c

                            3035,000d            552,425

                            34,000e

Manchester  6,000           30,000c               393,676

                            4045,000d

Birmingham  4,000           28,000b               400,757

                            30,000d

Leeds       2,000                              309,126

Sheffield   4,000            30,000c              284,410

                             20,000d

Bristol    29,000           100,000d              206,503

Nottingham  8,000            17,000f              111,631


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

II. England in 1760 5



Top




Page No 8


Norwich    28,000            40,000c               87,845

                             60,000d

Hull                      20,000c              161,519

                             24,000d

York       10,000                               59,596

Exeter     10,000                               47,098

Worcester   8,000          1112,000c              40,422

a. Macaulay's History of England c. 3. 

b. Defoe's Tour (1725) 

c. Arthur Young (1769) 

d. Macpherson's Annals of Commerce (1769) 

e. Levi's History of British Commerce 

f. Eden's State of the Poor (1797) 

g. The Returns for 1881 are those of the parliamentary  district. 

Another point to be considered is the relation of rural to  urban  population. According to Gregory King,

writing in 1696,  London  contained 530,000 inhabitants, other cities and  markettowns, 870,000,  while

villages and hamlets numbered  4,100,000. Arthur Young, seventy  years later, calculated that  London

contained onesixth of the whole  population, and remarked  that, 'in flourishing countries,' as England,  'the

half of a  nation is found in towns.' Both estimates are very  unreliable,  apart from the fact that both, and

especially that of  Arthur  Young, overestimate the total number of the population, but the  contrast between

them justly indicates the tendency of towns even  then to grow out of proportion to the rural districts. That

disproportion has, of course, become even more marked since  Arthur  Young's day. In 1881 the total urban

population was  17,285,026, or  66.6 per cent, while the rural was 8,683,026, or  33.3 per cent. 

The only estimates of occupations with which I am acquainted  are  again those of Gregory King in 1696, and

Arthur Young in  1769. They  are too vague, and too inconsistent with one another,  to be relied on,  but I give

them for what they are worth.  According to the former,  freeholders and their families numbered  940,000,

farmers and their  families, 750,000, labouring people  and out servants, 1,275,000,  cottagers and paupers,

1,300,000;  making a total agricultural  population of 4,265,000, against only  240,000 artisans and

handicraftsmen. Arthur Young estimates the  number of different classes  as follows: 

Farmers (whether freeholders or leaseholders),

their servants and labourers............... 2,800,000

Manufacturers of all kinds................. 3,000,000

Landlords and their dependents, fishermen

and miners................................... 800,000

Persons engaged in commerce.................. 200,000

Nonindustrious poor......................... 500,000

Clergy and lawyers........................... 200,000

Civil servants, army and navy................ 500,000

Total..................................... 8,500,000


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

II. England in 1760 6



Top




Page No 9


But the number set down to manufactures here is probably as much  too  high. In proportion to the total

population, as the total  itself is in  excess of the fact. 

III England in 1760

Agriculture 

In describing the agriculture of the time the first point of  importance is the proportion of cultivated land to

waste. Gregory  King, who rather overestimated the total acreage of England and  Wales, put the arable land at

11,000,000 acres, pasture and  meadow at  10,000,000, houses, gardens, orchards, etc., at  1,000,000, being a

total of 22,000,000 acres of cultivated land,  or nearly threefifths  of the whole country. A landagent in 1727

believed onehalf of the  country to be waste. Arthur Young,  writing fifty years later, puts the  cultivated area

at a much  higher figure. Estimating the total acreage  of England alone at  54,000,000 acres, he considered that

52,000,000 of  these were in  arable and pasture, in equal proportions. 

One or other of the two firstmentioned estimates is  certainly  nearer the truth than the last. The exact

proportion  is, however,  impossible to determine. 

There is no respect in which the agricultural England of  today  differs more from that of the period which we

are  considering, than in  the greatly reduced amount of common land,  The enclosure of commons  had been

going on for centuries before  1760, but with nothing like the  rapidity with which it has been  going on since, it

is known that  554,974 acres were enclosed  between 1710 and 1760, while nearly  7,000,000 were enclosed

between 1760 and 1845.4 At the beginning of  the latter period a  large proportion of this land, since enclosed,

was  under the  primitive tillage of the commonfields. Throughout  considerable  districts the agrarian system

of the middle ages still  existed in  full force. Some parishes had no common or waste lands  belonging  to them,

but where common lands were cultivated, one and the  same  plan was generally pursued. The arable land of

each village was  divided into three great stripes subdivided by 'baulks' three  yards  wide. Every farmer would

own at least one piece of land in  each field,  and all were bound to follow the customary tillage.  One strip was

left  fallow every year; on the other two were grown  wheat and barley;  sometimes oats, pease, or tares were

substituted for the latter. The  meadows were also held in common.  Up to hay harvest, indeed, every man  had

his own plot, but, while  in the arable land the plots rarely  changed hands, in the meadows  the different shares

were apportioned by  lot every year, After  hayharvest the fences in the meadow land were  thrown down, and

all householders had common rights of grazing on it.  Similarly  the stubbles were grazed, but here the right

was rarely open  to  all. Every farmer had the right of pasture on the waste. 

Though these common fields contained the best soil in the  kingdom,  they exhibited the most wretched

cultivation. 'Never,'  says Arthur  Young, 'were more miserable crops seen than all the  spring ones in the

common fields; absolutely beneath contempt.  The causes of this  deficient tillage were three in number: (1)

The same course of crops  was necessary. No proper rotation was  feasible; the only possible  alternation being

to vary the  proportions of different whitestraw  crops.  There were no  turnips or artificial grasses, and

consequently  no sheepfarming  on a large scale. Such sheep as there were were  miserably small;  the whole

carcase weighed only 28 lbs., and the  fleeces 3 1/2  lbs. each, as against 9 lbs. on sheep in enclosed  fields. (2)

Much time was lost by labourers and cattle 'in travelling  to many  dispersed pieces of land from one end of a

parish to another.'  (3) Perpetual quarrels arose about rights of pasture in the  meadows  and stubbles, and

respecting boundaries; in some fields  there were no  'baulks' to divide the plots, and men would plough  by

night to steal a  furrow from their neighbours. 

For these reasons the connections between the practice of  enclosing and improved agriculture was very close.

The early  enclosures, made under the Statutes of Merton (1235), and  Westminster  (1285), were taken by the

lords of the manor from the  waste. But in  these uses the lord had first to prove that  sufficient pasturage had


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

III England in 1760 7



Top




Page No 10


been left for the commoners; and if  rights of common existed  independent of the possession of land,  no

enclosure was permitted.  These early enclosures went on  steadily, but the enclosures which  first attract notice

towards  the end of the fifteenth century were of  a different kind. They  were often made on cultivated land,

and, if  Nasse is correct,  they took the form not only of permanent conversions  from arable  into pasture, but of

temporary conversions of arable into  pasture, followed by reconversion from pasture into arable. The  result

was a great increase of produce. The lord having separated  his  plots from those of his neighbours, and having

consolidated  them,  could pursue any system of tillage which seemed good to  him. The  alternate and

convertible husbandry, mentioned above,  was introduced;  the manure of the cattle enriched the arable  land,

and 'the grass  crops on the land ploughed up and manured  were much stronger and of a  better quality than

those on the  constant pasture.' Under the old  system the manure was spread on  the ground pasture, while in

the  enclosures it was used for the  benefit of land broken up for tillage.  The great enclosures of  the sixteenth

century took place in Suffolk,  Essex, Kent, and  Northamptonshire, which were in consequence the most

wealthy  counties. They were frequent also in Oxford, Berks,  Warwickshire,  Bedfordshire, Bucks, and

Leicestershire, and with  similar  results. In Arthur Young's time Norfolk, Suffolk, Essex, and  Kent  were the

best cultivated parts of England. 

Taking a general view of the state of agriculture in 1760, we  find  that improvements were confined to a few

parts of the  country. The  first enclosure Bill (1710) was to legalise the  enclosure of a parish  in Hampshire. I

have looked through twelve  of these Bills of the reign  of George I, and I find that they  applied to parishes in

Derbyshire,  Lancashire, Yorkshire,  Staffordshire, Somersetshire, Gloucestershire,  Wilts,  Warwickshire, and

Norfolk. But though enclosures were thus  widely  distributed, certain counties continued to bear a much

higher  reputation than others, and in some improvements were confined to  one  or two parishes, and not

spread over a wide district. The  best  cultivated counties were those which had long been enclosed.  Kent,

which was spoken of by William Stafford in 1581 as a county  where much  of the land was enclosed, is

described by Arthur Young  as having 'long  been reckoned the best cultivated in England.'...  'It must astonish

strangers,' he says, 'to East Kent and Thanet,  to find such numbers of  common farmers that have more drilled

crops than broadcast ones, and  to see them so familiar with  drillploughs and horsehoes. The drill  culture

carried on in so  complete a manner is the great peculiarity of  this country....  Hops are extremely well

cultivated.' Is in, another  passage he  says that Kent and Hertfordshire 'have the reputation of a  very  accurate

cultivation.' The Marquis of Rockingham brought a  Hertfordshire farmer to teach his tenants in the West

Riding to  hoe  turnips. The husbandry both of that district and of the East  Riding  was very backward. The

courses of crops, and the general  management of  the arable land were very faulty; very few of the  farmers

hoed  turnips, and those who did executed the work in so  slovenly a way that  neither the crop nor the land was

the least  the better for it; beans  were never hoed at all. The husbandry of  Northumberland, on the other  hand,

was much superior to that of  Durham and Yorkshire. Turnips were  hoed, manure was better  managed, and

potatoes were cultivated on a  large scale. Essex,  held up by Tusser in the reign of Elizabeth as an  example of

the  advantages of enclosures, and described by Young in  1807 as  having 'for ages been an enclosed country,'

is mentioned as  early  as 1694 as a county where 'some have their fallow after turnips,  which feed their sheep

in winter,'  the first mention of turnips  as  a field crop. 

But the greatest progress in the first half of the eighteenth  century seems to have taken place in Norfolk.

Every one has heard  of  Townshend growing turnips at Raynham, after his quarrel with  Walpole;  and Young,

writing in 1812, after speaking of the period  17001760 as  one of stagnation, owing to low prices ('it is

absolutely vain to  expect improvements in agriculture unless  prices are more disposed to  rise than to remain

long without  variations that give encouragement to  the farmer'), admits that  the improvements made in

Norfolk during that  time were an  exception, in his Eastern Tour (1770), he had spoken of  the  husbandry

'which has rendered the name of this county so famous  in the £arming world". and given seven reasons for

the  improvements.  These were: (1) Enclosing without assistance of  Parliament.  Parliamentary enclosure

'through the knavery of  commissioners and  attorneys,' was very expensive. 'Undoubtedly  many of the finest

loams  on the richest marls would at this day  have been sheepwalks had there  been any right o£ commonage

on  them.' (2) Marling, for there was  plenty of marl under the sand  everywhere; (3) An excellent rotation of


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

III England in 1760 8



Top




Page No 11


cropsthe famous Norfolk  four years' course of turnips, barley, clover  (or clover and  ryegrass), and wheat;

(4) The culture of turnips well  handhoed;  (5) The culture of clover and ryegrass; (6) The granting  of long

leases; (7) The division of the county chiefly into large  farms.  'Great farms,' he says, 'have been the soul of

the Norfolk  culture, though in the eastern part of the county there were  little  occupiers of £100 a year. 

Throughout the whole of the South of England, however, there  had  been a certain amount of progress.

Hoeing turnips, according  to Young,  was common in many parts of the south of the kingdom,  although the

extensive use of turnips  i.e. all their uses for  fattening cattle as  well as feeding lean sheep  'is known but

little of, except in  Norfolk, Suffolk, and Essex.' Clover  husbandry, on the other hand, was  'universal from the

North of  England to the further end of  Glamorganshire.' Clover, the 'great  clover,' had been introduced into

England by Sir Richard Weston  about 1645, as had probably been turnips  also. Potatoes at the  beginning of

the century were only garden crops.  Hemp and flax  were frequently grown, as were also hops, which had

been  introduced in the beginning of the sixteenth century. 

If we turn from the cultivation of the soil to the management  and  breeding of live stock, we shall find that no

great progress  had been  made in this branch during the years 17001760. Davenant  in 1700  estimated the net

carcase of black cattle at 370 lb., and  of a sheep  at 28 lb. A century later Eden calculated that  'bullocks now

killed in  London weigh, at an average, 800 lb.,  sheep 80 lb., and lambs about 50  lb. each". and Young in 1786

put  the weight of bullocks and sheep at  840 lb. and 100 lb.  respectively. But this improvement seems to have

come about after  1760. It was not until 176085 that Bakewell  perfected the new  breed of sheep  the

Leicesters  and improved the  breed of  longhorned cattle, and that the brothers Culley obtained the

shorthorn, or Durham cattle, from the breed in the valley of the  Tees. Some improvements in the breed of

sheep, however, had  already  been made. 'The wool of Warwickshire, Northamptonshire,  Lincolnshire,  and

Rutland, with some parts of Huntingdon,  Bedford, Buckinghamshire,  Cambridgeshire, and Norfolk has been

accounted the longest and finest  combing wool. But of late years'  (this was written in 1739) 'there  have been

improvements made in  the breed of sheep by changing or rams  and sowing of turnips and  grass seeds, and

now there is some large  fine combing wool to be  found in most counties in England, which is  fine, long, and

soft,  fit to make all sorts of fine stuff and hose  of.' Still  improvements in feeding sheep were by no means

universally  adopted for half a century later. Agricultural implements, too,  were  still very primitive, wooden

ploughs being commonly in use,  while the  small, narrowwheeled waggon of the North held 40 or 50  bushels

with  difficulty. 

Arthur Young constantly attributes much of the bad  agriculture to  the low rentals prevalent. 'Of so little

encouragement to them,' he  writes of the farmers of Cleveland,  'is the lowness of their rents,  that many large

tracts of land  that yielded good crops of corn within  thirty years are now  overrun with whins, brakes, and

other  trumpery.... If I be  demanded how such ill courses are to be stopped,  I answer, Raise  their rents. First

with moderation, and if that does  not bring  forth industry, double them.' At the same time Young  strongly

advocated long leases. But it must be remembered that besides  tenant farmers there were still a large number

of freeholders and  still more copyholders either for life or by inheritance. 

On the whole, though the evidence on some points is somewhat  contradictory, the progress of agriculture

between 1700 and 1760  may  be said to have been slow. Writing in 1770 Arthur Young  ascribes to  the last ten

years 'more experiments, more  discoveries, and more  general good sense displayed in the walk of  agriculture

than in an  hundred preceding ones.' Though  drillhusbandry was practised by  Jethro Tull, 'a gentleman of

Berkshire,' as early as 1701, and his  book was published in 1731,  'he seems to have had few followers in

England for more than  thirty years,' and Young in 1770 speaks of 'the  new husbandry' as  having sunk with

Tull, and 'not again put in motion  till within a  few years.' On the other hand, we have as early as 1687  Petty's

notice of 'the draining of fens, watering of dry grounds, and  improving of forests and commons.' Macpherson

in the year 1729  speaks  of the great sums lately expended in the enclosing and  improving of  lands; and

Laurence in 1727 asserts that 'it is an  undoubted truth  that the Art of Husbandry is of late years  greatly

improved, and  accordingly many estates have already  admitted their utmost  improvement, but,' he adds,


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

III England in 1760 9



Top




Page No 12


'much the  greater number still remains of  such as are so far from being  brought to that perfection that they

have felt few or none of the  effects of modern arts and experiments.' 

Still, in spite of the ignorance and stupidity of the farmers  and  their use of wretched implements, the average

produce of  wheat was  large. In 1770 it was twentyfive bushels to the acre,  when in France  it was only

eighteen. At the beginning of the  century some of our  colonies imported wheat from the mother  country. The

average export of  grain from 1697 to 1765 was nearly  500,000 quarters, while the imports  came to a very

small figure.  The exports were sent to Russia, Holland,  and America. 

IV England in 1760

Manufactures and Trade 

Among the manufactures of the time the woollen business was  by far  the most important. 'All our measures,'

wrote Bishop  Berkeley in 1737,  'should tend towards the immediate  encouragement of our woollen

manufactures, which must be looked  upon as the basis of our wealth.'  In 1701 our woollen exports  were

worth £2,000,000, or 'above a fourth  part of the whole  export trade.' In 1770 they were worth £4,000,000,  or

between a  third and a fourth of the whole. The territorial  distribution of  the manufacture was much the same

as now. This  industry had  probably existed in England from an early date. It is  mentioned  in a law of 1224. In

1331 John Kennedy brought the art of  weaving  woollen cloth from Flanders into England, and received the

protection of the king, who at the same time invited over fullers  and  dyers. There is extant a petition of the

worsted weavers and  merchants  of Norwich to Edward III in 1348. The coarse cloths of  Kendal and the  fine

cloths of Somerset, Dorset, Bristol, and  Gloucester are mentioned  in the statutes of the same century. In  1391

we hear of Guildford  cloths, and in 1467 of the woollen  manufacture in  DevonshireatLifton, Tavistock,

and Rowburgh. In  1402 the manufacture  was settled to a great extent in and near  London, but it gradually

shifted, owing to the high price of  labour and provisions, to Surrey,  Kent, Essex, Berkshire, and  Oxfordshire,

and afterwards still further,  into the counties of  Dorset, Wilts, Somerset, Gloucester, and  Worcester, and even

as  far as Yorkshire. 

There were three chief districts in which the woollen trade  was  carried on about 1760. One of these owed its

manufacture to  the wars  in the Netherlands. In consequence of Alva's  persecutions (15678)  many Flemings

settled in Norwich (which had  been desolate since Ket's  rebellion in 1549), Colchester.  Sandwich,

Canterbury, Maidstone, and  Southampton, The two former  towns seem to have benefited most from the  skill

of these  settlers so far as the woollen manufacture was  concerned. It was  at this time, according to

Macpherson, that Norwich  'learned the  making of those fine and slight stuffs which have ever  since gone  by

its name,' such as crapes, bombayines, and camblets;  while the  baiyemakers settled at Colchester and its

neighbourhood.  The  stuffs thus introduced into England were known as the 'new  drapery', and included baiye,

serges, and other slight woollen  goods  as distinguished from the 'old drapery,' a term applied to  broad  cloth,

kersies, etc. 

The chief seats of the West of England manufacture were  Bradford  in Wilts, the centre of the manufacture of

superfine  cloth; Devizes,  famous for its serges; Warminster and Frome, with  their fine cloth;  Trowbridge;

Stroud, the centre of the  dyedcloth manufactures; and  Taunton, which in Defoe's time  possessed 1100

looms. The district  reached from Cirencester in  the north to Sherborne in the south, and  from Witney in the

east  to Bristol in the west, being about fifty  miles in length where  longest, and twenty in breadth where

narrowest   'a rich enclosed  country,' as Defoe says, 'full of rivers and towns,  and  infinitely populous,

insomuch that some of the market towns are  equal to cities in bigness, and superior to many of them in

numbers  of people.' It was a 'prodigy of a trade,' and the 'fine  Spanish  medley cloths' which this district

produced were worn by  'all the  persons of fashion in England.' It was no doubt the  presence of  streams and

the Cotswold wool which formed the  attractions of the  district. A branch of the industry extended  into Devon,


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IV England in 1760 10



Top




Page No 13


where the  merchants of Exeter bought in a rough state  the serges made in the  country round, to dye and finish

them for  home consumption or export. 

The third chief seat of the manufacture was the West Riding  of  Yorkshire, where the worsted trade centred

round Halifax,  which,  according to Camden, began to manufacture about 1537; and  where Leeds  and its

neighbourhood manufactured a coarse cloth of  English wool. In  1574 the manufacturers of the West Riding

made  56,000 pieces of broad  cloth and 72,000 of narrow. It will be  seen from this short survey  that, however

greatly the production  of these different districts may  have changed in proportion since  1760, the several

branches of the  trade are even now distributed  very much as they were then, the West  Riding being the

headquarters of the worsted and coarse cloth trade,  while Norwich  still keeps the crape industry, and the West

manufactures fine  cloth. 

The increased demand for English wool consequent upon the  extension of this industry led to large

enclosures of land,  especially in Northamptonshire, Rutlandshire, Leicestershire, and  Warwickshire, which

counties supplied most of the combing wools  used  for worsted stuffs and stockings; but parts of Huntingdon,

Bedford,  Bucks, Cambridgeshire, Romney Marsh, and Norfolk  competed with them,  and by 1739 most

counties produced the fine  combing wool. Defoe  mentions the sale of wool from Lincolnshire,  'where the

longest staple  is found, the sheep of those parts  being of the largest breed". and in  Arthur Young's time

Lincolnshire and Leicestershire wools were still  used at Norwich.  The Cotswold and Isle of Wight sheep

yielded clothing  or short  wools, 'but they were inferior to the best Spanish wools,'  and  could not 'enter into

the composition without spoiling and  degrading in some degree the fabric of the cloth.' Consequently  in  the

West of England, occupied as it was with the production of  the  finest cloths, Spanish wool was largely used,

though shortly  before  Young's time it was discovered that 'Norfolk sheep yielded  a wool  about their necks

equal to the best from Spain.' 

Next in importance was the iron trade, which was largely  carried  on, though by this time a decaying industry,

in the Weald  of Sussex,  where in 1740 there were ten furnaces, producing  annually 1400 tons.  The trade had

reached its chief extent in the  seventeenth century, but  in 1724 was still the principal  manufacturing interest

of the county.  The balustrades which  surround St. Paul's were cast at Lamberhurst,  and their weight,

including the seven gates, is above 200 tons. They  cost £11,000.  Gloucestershire, Shropshire, and Yorkshire

had each six  furnaces.  In the latter county, which boasted an annual produce of  1400  tons, the most famous

works were at Rotherham. There were also  great ironworks at Newcastle. 

In 1755 an ironmaster named Anthony Bacon had got a lease for  ninetynine years of a district eight miles in

length, by five in  breadth, at MerthyrTydvil, upon which he erected iron and coal  works. In 1709 the

Coalbrookdale works in Shropshire were  founded,  and in 1760 Carron iron was first manufactured in

Scotland.  Altogether, there were about 1737 fiftynine furnaces  in eighteen  different counties, producing

17,350 tons annually.  It has been  computed that we imported 20,000 tons. In 1881 we  exported 3,820,315

tons of iron and steel, valued at £27,590,908,  and imported to the  value of £3,705,332. 

The cotton trade was still so insignificant as to be  mentioned  only once, and that incidentally by Adam Smith.

It was  confined to  Lancashire, where its headquarters were Manchester  and Bolton. In 1760  not more than

40,000 persons were engaged in  it, and the annual value  of the manufactures was estimated at  £600,000. The

exports, however,  were steadily growing; in 1701  they amounted to £23,253, in 1751 to  £45,986, in 1764 to

£200,354. Burke about this time spoke of 'that  infinite variety  of admirable manufactures that grow and

extend every  year among  the spirited, inventive, and enterprising traders of  Manchester.'  But even in 1764

our exports of cotton were still only  onetwentieth of the value of the wool exports. 

The hardware trade then as now was located chiefly in  Sheffield  and Birmingham, the latter town employing

over 50,000  people in that  industry. The business, however, was not so much  concentrated as now,  and there

were small workshops scattered  about the kingdom. 'Polished  steel,' for instance, was  manufactured at


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IV England in 1760 11



Top




Page No 14


Woodstock, locks in South  Staffordshire, pins at  Warrington, Bristol, and Gloucester, where they  were 'the

staple  of the city.' The hosiery trade, too, was as yet only  in process  of concentration. By 1800 the

manufacture of silk hosiery  had  centred in Derby, that of woollen hosiery in Leicester, though  Nottingham

had not yet absorbed the cotton hosiery. But at the  beginning of the century there were still many looms

round  London,  and in other parts of the South of England. In 1750  London had 1000  frames, Surrey 350,

Nottingham 1500, Leicester  1000, Derby 200, other  places in the Midlands, 7300; other  English and Scotch

towns, 1850;  Ireland, 800; Total, 14,000. Most  of the silk was woven in  Spitalfields, but first spun in the

North at Stockport, Knutsford,  Congleton, and Derby. In 1770  there was a silkmill at Sheffield on  the model

of Derby, and a  manufactory of waste silk at Kendal.  Coventry had already, in  Defoe's time, attracted the

ribbon business.  In 1721 the silk  manufacture was said to be worth £700,000 a yew more  than at the

Revolution. 

Linen was an ancient manufacture in England, and had been  introduced into Dundee at the beginning of the

seventeenth  century.  In 1746 the British Linen Company was incorporated to  supply Africa  and the American

plantations with linen made at  home, and Adam Smith  considered it a growing manufacture. It was,  of

course, the chief  manufacture of Ireland, where it had been  further developed by French  Protestants, who

settled there at the  end of the seventeenth century. 

The mechanical arts were still in a very backward state. In  spite  of the fact that the woollen trade was the

staple industry  of the  country, the division of labour in it was in Adam Smith's  time 'nearly  the same as it was

a century before, and the  machinery employed not  very different.' According to the same  author there had

been only  three inventions of importance since  Edward IV's reign: the exchange  of the rock and spindle for

the  spinningwheel; the use of machines  for facilitating the proper  arrangement of the warp and woof before

being put into the loom;  and the employment of fulling mills for  thickening cloth instead  of treading it in

water. In this enumeration,  however, he forgot  to mention the flyshuttle, invented in 1738 by  Kay, a native

of  Bury, in Lancashire, the first of the great  inventions which  revolutionised the woollen industry. Its utility

consisted in its  enabling a weaver to do his work in half the time,  and making it  possible for one man instead

of two to weave the widest  cloth. 

'The machines used in the cotton manufacture,' says Baines,  'were,  up to the year 1760, nearly as simple as

those of India;  though the  loom was more strongly and perfectly constructed, and  cards for  combing the

cotton had been adapted from the woollen  manufacture. None  but the strong cottons, such as fustians and

dimities, were as yet  made in England, and for these the demand  must always have been  limited.' In 1758

John Wyatt invented  spinning by rollers, but the  discovery never proved profitable.  In 1760 the

manufacturers of  Lancashire began to use the  flyshuttle. Calico printing was already  largely developed. 

The reason why division of labour was carried out to so small  an  extent, an invention so rare and so little

regarded, is given  by Adam  Smith himself. Division of labour, as he points out, is  limited by the  extent of the

market, and, owing chiefly to bad  means of  communication, the market for English manufactures was  still a

very  narrow one. Yet England, however slow the  development o£ her  manufactures, advanced nevertheless

more  rapidly in this respect than  other nations. One great secret of  her progress lay in the facilities  for

watercarriage afforded by  her rivers, for all communication by  land was still in the most  neglected

condition. A second cause was the  absence of internal  customs barriers, such as existed in France, and  in

Prussia until  Stein's time. The home trade of England was  absolutely free. 

Arthur Young gives abundant evidence of the execrable state  of the  roads. It took a week or more for a coach

to go from  London to  Edinburgh. On 'that infernal' road between Preston and  Wigan the ruts  were four feet

deep, and he saw three carts break  down in a mile of  road. At Warrington the turnpike was 'most  infamously

bad,' and  apparently 'made with a view to immediate  destruction.' 'Very shabby,'  'execrable,' 'vile,' 'most

execrably  vile,' are Young's ordinary  comments on the highways. But the  water routes for traffic largely  made

up for the deficiencies of  the land routes. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IV England in 1760 12



Top




Page No 15


Attempts to improve water communication began with deepening  the  river beds. In 16S5 there was a project

for rendering the  Avon  navigable from its junction with the Severn at Tewkesbury  through  Gloucestershire,

Worcestershire, and Warwickshire, but it  was  abandoned owing to the civil war. From 1660 to 1755 various

Acts were  passed for deepening the beds of rivers. In 1720 there  was an Act for  making the Mersey and

Irwell navigable between  Liverpool and  Manchester. About the same time the navigation of  the Aire and

Calder  was opened out. In 1755 the first canal was  made, eleven miles in  length, near Liverpool. Three years

later  the Duke of Bridgewater had  another constructed £rom his coal  mines at Worsley to Manchester,  seven

miles distant. Between 1761  and 1766 a still longer one of  twentynine miles was completed  from

Manchester through Chester to the  Mersey above Liverpool.  From this time onwards the canal system spread

with great  rapidity. 

When we turn to investigate the industrial organisation of  the  time, we that the class of capitalist employers

was as  yet but in its  infancy. A large part of our goods were still  produced on the domestic  system.

Manufactures were little  concentrated in towns, and only  partially separated from  agriculture. The

'manufacturer, was,  literally, the man who  worked with his own hands in his own cottage.  Nearly the whole

cloth trade of the West Riding, for instance, was  organised on  this system at the beginning of the century. 

An important feature in the industrial organisation of the  time  was the existence of a number of small

mastermanufacturers,  who were  entirely independent, having capital and land of their  own, for they

combined the culture of small freehold  pasturefarms with their  handicraft. Defoe has left an  interesting

picture of their life. The  land near Halifax, he  says, was 'divided into small Enclosures from  two Acres to six

or  seven each, seldom more, every three or four  Pieces of Land had  an House belonging to them;... hardly an

House  standing out of a  Speaking distance from another;... we could see at  every House a  Tenter, and on

almost every Tenter a piece of Cloth or  Kersie or  Shaloon.... Every clothier keeps one horse, at least, to  carry

his Manufactures to the Market; and every one, generally, keeps  a  Cow or two or more for his Family. By this

means the small Pieces  of enclosed Land about each house are occupied, for they scarce  sow  Corn enough to

feed their Poultry.... The houses are full of  lusty  Fellows, some at the Dyevat, some at the looms, others

dressing the  Cloths; the women and children carding or spinning;  being all employed  from the youngest to

the oldest.... Not a  Beggar to be seen nor an  idle person.' 

This system, however, was no longer universal in Arthur  Young's  time. That writer found at Sheffield a

silkmill  employing 152 hands,  including women and children; at Darlington  'one mastermanufacturer

employed above fifty looms'; at Boyton  there were 150 hands in one  factory. So, too, in the West of  England

clothtrade the germs of the  capitalist system were  visible. The rich merchant gave out work to  labourers in

the  surrounding villages, who were his employes, and were  not  independent. In the Nottingham hosiery trade

there were, in 1750,  fifty manufacturers, known as 'putters out,' who employed 1200  frames; in Leicestershire

1800 frames were so employed. In the  handmade nail business of Staffordshire and Worcestershire, the

merchant had warehouses in different parts of the district, and  give  out nailrod iron to the nailmaster,

sufficient for a  week's work for  him and his family. In Lancashire we can trace,  step by step, the  growth of

the capitalist employer. At first we  see, as in Yorkshire,  the weaver furnishing himself with warp and  weft,

which he worked up  in his own house and brought himself to  market. By degrees he found it  difficult to get

yarn from the  spinners; so the merchants at  Manchester gave him out linen warp  and raw cotton, and the

weaver  became dependent on them. Finally,  the merchant would get together  thirty or forty looms in a town.

This was the nearest approach to the  capitalist system before the  great mechanical inventions. 

Coming to the system of exchange, we find it based on several  different principles, which existed side by

side, but which were  all,  as we should think, very simple and primitive. Each trade  had its  centre in a

provincial town. Leeds, for instance, had its  market twice  a week, first on the bridge over the Aire,  afterwards

in the High  Street, where, at a later time, two halls  were built. Every clothier  had his stall, to which he would

bring  his cloth (seldom more than one  piece at a time, owing to the  frequency of the markets). At six or  seven

o'clock a bell rang,  and the market began; the merchants and  factors came in and made  their bargains with the


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IV England in 1760 13



Top




Page No 16


clothiers, and in  little more than an  hour the whole business was over. By nine the  benches were  cleared and

the hall empty. There was a similar hall at  Halifax  for the worsted trade. But a large portion of the inland

traffic  was carried on at fairs, which were still almost as important  as  in the Middle Ages. The most famous

of all was the great fair of  Sturbridge, which lasted from the middle of August to the middle  of  September.

Hither came representatives of all the great  trades. The  merchants of Lancashire brought their goods on a

thousand packhorses;  the Eastern counties sent their worsteds,  and Birmingham its hardware.  An immense

quantity of wool was  sold, orders being taken by the  wholesale dealers of London. In  fact, a large part of the

home trade  found its way to this  market. There were also the four great annual  fairs, which  retained the

ancient title of 'marts,' at Lynn, Boston,  Gainsborough, and Beverley. 

The link between these fairs and the chief industrial centres  was  furnished by travelling merchants. Some

would go from Leeds  with  droves of packhorses to all the fairs and markettowns  throughout  England. In

the markettowns they sold to the shops;  elsewhere they  would deal directly with the consumer, like the

Manchester merchants,  who sent their packhorses the round of the  farmhouses, buying wool or  other

commodities in exchange for  their finished goods. Sometimes the  London merchants would come  to the

manufacturers, paying their guineas  down at once, and  taking away the purchases themselves. So too in the

Birmingham  lock trade, chapmen would go round with packhorses to buy  from  manufacturers; in the brass

trade likewise the manufacturer  stayed at home, and the merchant came round with cash in his  saddlebags,

and put the brasswork which he purchased into them,  though in some cases he would order it to be sent by

carrier. 

Ready cash was essential, for banking was very little  developed.  The Bank of England existed, but before

1759 issued no  notes of less  value than £20. By a law of 1709 no other bank of  more than six  partners was

allowed; and in 1750, according to  Burke, there were not  more than 'twelve bankers' shops out of  London.'

The ClearingHouse  was not established till 1775. 

Hampered as the inland trade was by imperfect communications,  extraordinary efforts were made to promote

exchange. It is  striking  to find waste silk from London made into silkyarn at  Kendal and sent  back again, or

cattle brought from Scotland to  Norfolk to be fed. Many  districts, however, still remained  completely

excluded, so that  foreign products never reached them  at all. Even at the beginning of  this century the

Yorkshire  yeoman, as described by Southey was  ignorant of sugar, potatoes,  and cotton; the Cumberland

dalesman, as  he appears in  Wordsworth's Guide to the Lakes, lived entirely on the  produce of  his farm. It was

this domestic system which the great  socialist  writers Sismondi and Lassalle had in their minds when they

inveighed against the modern organisation of industry. Those who  lived under it, they pointed out, though

poor, were on the whole  prosperous; overproduction was absolutely impossible. Yet at the  time of which I

am speaking, many of the evils which modern  Socialists lament were already visible, especially in those

industries which produced for the foreign market. Already there  were  complaints of the competition of men

who pushed themselves  into the  market to take advantage of high prices; already we hear  of  fluctuations of

trade and irregularity of employment. The old  simple  conditions of production and exchange were on the eve

of  disappearance  before the allcorroding force of foreign trade. 

The home trade was still indeed much greater in proportion  than  now; but the exports had grown from about

£7,000,000 at the  beginning  of the century to £14,500,000 in 1760. During that  interval great  changes had

taken place in the channels of foreign  commerce. In 1700  Holland was our great market, taking more than

onethird of all our  exports, but in 1760 the proportion was  reduced to about oneseventh.  Portugal, which in

1703 took  oneseventh, now took only about  onetwelfth. The trade with  France was quite insignificant. On

the  other hand, the Colonies  were now our chief markets, and a third of  our exports went  there. In 1770

America took threefourths of all the  manufactures  of Manchester. In 1767 the exports to Jamaica were

nearly  as  great as they had been to all the English plantations together in  1704. The shipping trade had

doubled, and the ships themselves  were  larger. In 1732 ships 750 tons were considered remarkable;  in 1770

there were many in Liverpool of 900 tons; but in this as  in other  branches of business progress was still slow,


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IV England in 1760 14



Top




Page No 17


partial,  local, thus  presenting a striking contrast to the rapid and  general advance of the  next halfcentury. 

V. England in 1760

The Decay of the Yeomanry 

It is a reflection that must have occurred to every one that  the  popular philosophy of the day, while in the

region of  speculation it  has undermined ancient beliefs, has exerted in the  practical world a  distinctly

conservative influence. The  conception of slow development,  according to definite laws,  undoubtedly tends

to strengthen the  position of those who offer  resistance to radical changes. It may,  however, well be doubted

whether the theory of evolution is really  such a support as it  seems to be to those who would uphold the

existing framework of  society. It is certainly remarkable that the  most recent  legislation has been at once

revolutionary in its  character and  justified by appeals to historical experience. I do not  forget  that the most

distinguished exponent of the doctrine of  evolution  as applied to politics has developed a theory of

government  opposed to recent legislative reforms, but that theory is an a  priori  one. Those, on the other hand,

who have applied the  historical method  to political economy and the science of  society, have shown an

unmistakable disposition to lay bare the  injustice to which the  humbler classes of the community have been

exposed, and to defend  methods and institutions adopted for their  protection which have never  received

scientific defence before. 

The fact is, that the more we examine the actual course of  affairs, the more we are amazed at the unnecessary

suffering that  has  been inflicted upon the people. No generalities about natural  law or  inevitable development

can blind us to the fact, that the  progress in  which we believe has been won at the expense of much  injustice

and  wrong, which was not inevitable. Perhaps this is  most conspicuous in  our land system, and we shall find

with  regard to it, as with regard  to some other matters, that the more  we accept the method of  historical

inquiry, the more  revolutionary shall we tend to become in  practice, For while the  modern historical school of

economists appear  to be only  exploring the monuments of the past, they are really  shaking the  foundations of

many of our institutions in the present.  The  historical method is often deemed conservative, because it traces

the gradual and stately growth of our venerable institutions; but  it  may exercise a precisely opposite influence

by showing the  gross  injustice which was blindly perpetrated during this growth.  The  historical method is

supposed to prove that economic changes  have been  the inevitable outcome of natural laws. It just as  often

proves them  to have been brought about by the selfseeking  action of dominant  classes. 

It is a singular thing that no historian has attempted an  adequate  explanation of the disappearance of the small

freeholders who, down to  the close of the seventeenth century,  formed with their families  onesixth of the

population of  England, and whose stubborn  determination enabled Cromwell and  Fairfax to bring the Civil

War to a  successful close. This  neglect is the more remarkable, as economists  have so  emphatically dwelt

upon the extraordinary difference between  the  distribution of landed property in England and in countries like

Germany and France. The modern reformer is content to explain the  facts by the existence in England of a

law of primogeniture and a  system of strict settlement, but the explanation is obviously a  superficial one. To

show why in England the small landed  proprietors  have vanished, whilst in Germany and France they have

increased and  thriven, it is necessary to carry our inquiries far  back into the  history of law, politics, and

commerce. The result  of a closer  examination of the question is a little startling,  for we find that  the present

distribution of landed property in  England is in the main  due to the existence of the system of  political

government which has  made us a free people. And on the  other hand, the distribution of  landed property in

France and  Germany, which writer after writer  points to as the great bulwark  against revolution, is in the

main due  to a form of government  that destroyed political liberty and placed  the people in  subjection to the

throne. 

Evidence in support of this conclusion is not difficult to  adduce.  The first fact which arouses our interest is


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

V. England in 1760 15



Top




Page No 18


that at the  conclusion of  the seventeenth century it was estimated by Gregory  King that there  were 180,000

freeholders in England, and that,  less than a hundred  years later, the pamphleteers of the time,  and even

careful writers  like Arthur Young, speak of the small  freeholders as practically gone.  The bare statement of

this  contrast is in itself most impressive. A  person ignorant of our  history during the intervening period might

surmise that a great  exterminatory war had taken place, or a violent  social revolution  which had caused a

transfer of the property of one  class to  another. But though the surmise in this particular form would  be

incorrect, we are nevertheless justified in saying that a  revolution of incalculable importance had taken place,

a  revolution, though so silent, of as great importance as the  political  revolution of 1831. 'The able and

substantial  freeholders,' described  by Whitelock, 'the freeholders and  freeholders' sons, well armed  within

with the satisfaction of  their own good consciences, and  without by iron arms, who stood  firmly and charged

desperately,'   this devoted class, who had  broken the power of the king and the  squires in the Civil Wars,

were themselves, within a hundred years  from that time, being  broken, dispersed, and driven off the land.

Numerous and  prosperous in the fifteenth century, they had suffered  something  by the enclosures of the

sixteenth; but though complaints  are  from time to time made in the seventeenth of the laying together  of

farms, there is no evidence to show that their number  underwent  any great diminution during that time. In the

picture  of country life  which we find in the literature of the first  years of the eighteenth  century, the small

freeholder is still a  prominent figure. Sir Roger  de Coverley, in riding to Quarter  Sessions, points to the two

yeomen  who are riding in front of  him, and Defoe, in his admirable Tour  through England, first  published a

few years later, describes with  satisfaction the  number and prosperity of the Greycoats of Kent (as  they were

called from their homespun garments), whose political power  forced the gentlemen to treat them with

circumspection and  deference.  'Of the freeholders of England,' says Chamberlayne, in  the State of  Great

Britain, first published towards the close of  the seventeenth  century, 'there are more in number and richer

than in any country of  the like extent in Europe. £40 or £50 a  year is very ordinary, £100 or  £200 in some

counties is not rare;  sometimes in Kent, and in the Weald  of Sussex, £500 or £600 per  annum, and £3000 or

£4000 stock.' The  evidence is conclusive that  up to the Revolution of 1688 the  freeholders were in most parts

of the country an important feature in  social life. 

If, however, we ask whether they had possessed, as a class,  any  political initiative, we must answer in the

negative. In the  lists of  the Eastern Counties' Association, formed in the Civil  War (the  eastern counties were

the districts, perhaps, where the  freeholders  were strongest), we find no name which has not  appended to it

the  title of gentleman or esquire. The small  landed proprietor, though  courageous and independent in personal

character, was ignorant, and  incapable himself of taking the  lead. There was little to stimulate  his mind in his

country life;  in agriculture he pursued the same  methods as his forefathers,  was full of prejudices, and

difficult to  move. The majority of  this class had never travelled beyond their  native village or  homestead and

the neighbouring markettown. In some  districts  those freeholders were also artisans, especially in the

eastern  counties, which were still the richest part of the country,  and  the most subject to foreign influence.

But, on the whole, if we  may judge from the accounts of rather later times, the yeomen,  though  thriving in

good seasons, often lived very hard lives, and  remained  stationary in their habits and ways of thinking from

generation to  generation. They were capable in the Civil War,  under good leadership,  of proving themselves

the most powerful  body in the kingdom; but after  constitutional government had been  secured, and the great

landowners  were independent of their  support, they sank into political  insignificance. The Revolution  of

1688, which brought to a conclusion  the constitutional  struggle of the seventeenth century, was  accomplished

without  their aid, and paved the way for their  extinction. A revolution  in agricultural life was the price paid

for  political liberty. 

At first, however, the absorption of the small freeholders  went on  slowly. The process of disappearance has

been continuous  from about  1700 to the present day, but it is not true to say, as  Karl Marx does,  that the

yeomanry had disappeared by the middle  of the eighteenth  century. It was not till the very period which  we

are considering,  that is to say about 1760, that the process  of extinction became  rapid. There is conclusive

evidence that  many were still to be found  about 1770. There were at that time  still 9000 freeholders in Kent. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

V. England in 1760 16



Top




Page No 19


Even as late as 1807, estates in Essex, if divided, were  bought by  farmers at high prices, and there was some

prospect of  landed property  coming back to the conditions of a century  before, 'when our inferior  gentry

resided upon their estates in  the country'; and about the same  date there were in Oxfordshire  'many

proprietors of a middling size,  and many small proprietors,  particularly in the open fields.' They  were

especially strong in  Cumberland, the West Riding, and parts of  the East Riding. In the  Vale of Pickering in

1788 nearly the whole  district belonged to  them, and no great landowner had been able to get  a footing. But

in 1788 this was already an exceptional case, and in  other  writers of that period we find a general lament at

the  disappearance of the yeoman. Arthur Young 'sincerely regrets the  loss  of that set of men who are called

yeomen... who really kept  up the  independence of the nation,' and is 'loth to see their  lands now in  the hands

of monopolising lords;' and in 1787 he  admits that they had  practically disappeared from most parts o£  the

country. And with the  yeomen went the small squires, victims  o£ the same causes. 

These causes, as I stated above, are to be sought less in  economical than in social and political facts. The

chief of them  was  our peculiar form of government. After the Revolution the  landed  gentry were practically

supreme. Not only national but  local  administration was entirely in their hands, and, as a  natural

consequence, land, being the foundation of social and  political  influence, was eagerly sought after. We may

contrast  France and  Prussia, where the landowners had no political power  as such, and  where, in

consequence, small properties remained  unassailed. The  second fact is the enormous development of the

mercantile and moneyed  interest. The merchants could only obtain  political power and social  position by

becoming landowners. It is  true that Swift says that 'the  power which used to follow land  had gone over to

money,' and that the  great Turkey merchants,  like Addison's Sir Andrew Freeport, occupied a  good position;

but  few mere merchants were in Parliament, and Dr  Johnson made the  significant remark that 'an English

merchant is a new  species of  gentleman.' To make himself a gentleman, therefore, the  merchant  who had

accumulated his wealth in the cities, which, as we  have  seen, were growing rapidly during the first half of the

eighteenth century with an expanding commerce, bought land as a  matter of course. Hence the mercantile

origin of much of our  nobility. James Lowther, created Earl of Lonsdale in 1784, was  greatgrandson of a

Turkey merchant; the ancestor of the Barings  was  a clothier in Devonshire; Anthony Petty, father of Sir W.

Petty, and  the ancestor on the female side of the  PettyFitzmaurices, was a  clothier at Romsey, in Hampshire;

Sir  Josiah Child's son became Earl  of Tilney. The landowners in the  West of England, 'who now,' in  Defoe's

words, 'carry their heads  so high,' made their fortunes in the  clothing trade. And not only  did a new race of

landowners thus spring  up, but the old families  enriched themselves, and so were enabled to  buy more land

by  intermarriage with the commercial magnates. The  Fitzmaurices, for  instance, inherited the wealth of the

Pettys:  Child's daughter  married the Marquis of Worcester, and, by a second  marriage, Lord  Grenville of

Potheridge; Lord Conway and Walpole  married  daughters of John Shorter, merchant of London. 'I think I

remember,' said Sir R. Temple between 1675 and 1700, 'the first  noble  families that married into the City for

money.' 'Trade,'  said Defoe,  'is so far here from being inconsistent with a  gentleman, that, in  short, trade in

England makes gentlemen; for,  after a generation or  two, the tradesmen's children, or at least  their

grandchildren, come  to be as good gentlemen, statesmen,  parliamentmen, privycouncillors,  judges,

bishops, and noblemen,  as those of the highest birth, and the  most ancient families.'  Contrast this fusion of

classes with the  French society of the  last century, with its impoverished nobility,  living often on the

seignorial rights and rentcharges of their  alienated estates,  but hardly ever intermarrying with the

commercial  classes; or  that of Prussia, where the two classes remained entirely  separate, and could not even

purchase one another's land. 

I have established two facts: the special reason for desiring  land  after the Revolution as a condition of

political power and  social  prestige, and the means of buying land on the part of the  wealthy  merchants or of

the nobility and greater gentry enriched  by  matrimonial alliances with the great commercial class. Now  here

is a  piece of evidence to show that it was the accepted  policy of the large  landowners to buy out the yeoman.

The land  agent, whom I have so often  quoted, lays down as a maxim for the  model steward that he 'should

not  forget to make the best inquiry  into the disposition of the  freeholders, within or near any of  his lord's

manors, to sell their  lands, that he may use his best  endeavours to purchase them at as  reasonable a price as


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

V. England in 1760 17



Top




Page No 20


may be  for his lord's advantage and  convenience.' 

On the other hand, as a result of the supremacy of the great  landowners in Parliament, their own estates were

artificially  protected. The system of strict settlements, introduced by Sir  Orlando Bridgman in 1666, though

not so important as it is often  made  out to be, prevented much land from coming into the market,  though it

did not prevent merchants from buying when they wished.  The custom of  primogeniture checked the division

of estates by  leading to the disuse  of inheritance by gavelkind, and similar  customs. In Cumberland

primogeniture was introduced among the  freeholders in the sixteenth  century. In Kent there was, in 1740,

nearly as much gavelkind as  before the disgavelling Acts began,  but thirty years later it was  being superseded

by primogeniture.  It was during these thirty years  that the process of  concentration in that county first

assumed  formidable  proportions. In Pickering, on the other hand, where the law  of  equal division still held its

own, small landowners al so, as we  have seen, survived after their extinction in most parts of  England. 

A third result of landlord supremacy was the manner in which  the  commonfield system was broken up.

Allusion has already been  made to  enclosures, and enclosures meant a breakup of the old  system of

agriculture and a redistribution of the land. This is a  problem which  involves delicate questions of justice. In

Prussia,  the change was  effected by impartial legislation; in England, the  work was done by  the strong at the

expense of the weak. The  change from common to  individual ownership, which was  economically

advantageous, was carried  out in an iniquitous  manner, and thereby became socially harmful.  Great injury

was  thus done to the poor and ignorant freeholders who  lost their  rights in the common lands. In Pickering, in

one instance,  the  lessee of the tithes applied for an enclosure of the waste. The  small freeholders did their best

to oppose him, but, having  little  money to carry on the suit, they were overruled, and the  lessee, who  had

bought the support of the landless 'houseowners'  of the parish,  took the land from the freeholders and shared

the  spoil with the  cottagers. It was always easy for the steward to  harass the small  owners till he forced them

to sell, like  Addison's Touchy, whose  income had been reduced by lawsuits from  £80 to £30, though in this

case it is true he had only himself to  blame. The enclosure of waste  land, too, did great damage to the  small

freeholders, who, without the  right of grazing, naturally  found it so much the more difficult to pay  their way. 

Though the economical causes of the disappearance of the  yeomen  were comparatively unimportant, they

served to accelerate  the change.  Small arable farms would not pay, and must, in any  case, have been  thrown

together. The little farmers, according to  Arthur Young, worked  harder and were to all intents and purposes

as low in the comforts of  life as the daylabourers. But their  wretchedness was entirely owing  to their

occupying arable instead  of grass lands. And apart from this,  undoubtedly, the new class  of large farmers

were superior, in some  respects, to the too  unprogressive yeomen,  'quite a different sort  of men... In  point

of knowledge and ideas,' with whose improved  methods of  agriculture the yeomen found it difficult to

compete. A  further  economic cause which tended to depress many of the yeomen was  the  gradual destruction

of domestic industries, which injured them as  it injures the German peasant at the present day, in Cumberland

the  yeomen began to disappear when the spinningwheel was  silenced. The  decay of the home manufacture

of cloth seems to  have considerably  affected the Greycoats of Kent. And finally,  as the small towns and

villages decayed, owing to the  consolidation of farms and of industry,  the small freeholders  lost their market,

for the badness of the roads  made it difficult  for them to send their produce far. Hence the small  freeholders

survived longest where they owned dairyfarms, as in  Cumberland  and the West Riding, and where domestic

industry  flourished, and  they had a market for their products in their own  neighbourhood. 

When once the ranks of the yeomanry had been appreciably  thinned,  the process of extinction went on with

evergrowing  rapidity. The  survivors became isolated. They would have no one  of their own station  to whom

they could marry their daughters,  and would become more and  more willing to sell their lands,  however

strong the passion of  possession might be in some places.  The more enterprising, too, would  move off to the

towns to make  their fortunes there, just as at the  present day the French  peasants are attracted to the more

interesting  and exciting life  of the town. Thus Sir Robert Peel's grandfather was  originally a  yeoman farming

his own estate, but being of an inventive  turn of  mind he took to cotton manufacturing and printing. This was


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

V. England in 1760 18



Top




Page No 21


particularly the case with the small squires, who grew  comparatively  poorer and poorer, and found it

increasingly  difficult to keep pace  with the rise in the standard of comfort.  Already, at the end of the

seventeenth century, the complaint had  been raised that the landowners  were beginning to live in the  county

towns. Afterwards, the more  wealthy came up to London; Sir  Roger de Coverley had a house in Soho  Square.

The small country  gentleman felt the contrast between him and  his richer neighbours  more and more; and as

he had none of the  political power  attaching to landfor the great landowners had the  whole  administration in

their handsthere was every inducement for him  to sell and invest his money in a more profitable manner. 

To summarise the movement: it is probable that the yeomen  would in  any case have partly disappeared,

owing to the  inevitable working of  economic causes. But these alone would not  have led to their

disappearance on so large a scale. It was the  political conditions of  the age, the overwhelming importance of

land, which made it impossible  for the yeoman to keep his grip  upon the soil. 

VI. England in 1760

The Condition of the WageEarners 

The condition of the agricultural labourer had very much  improved  since the beginning of the century. In the

seventeenth  century his  average daily wage had been 10 1/4d., while the  average price of corn  had been 38s.

2d. During the first sixty  years of the eighteenth  century his average wages were 1s., the  price of corn 32s.

Thus, while  the price of corn had, thanks to a  succession of good seasons, fallen  16 per cent, wages had risen

to about an equal extent, and the  labourer was thus doubly  benefited. Adam Smith attributes this advance  in

prosperity to  'an increase in the demand for labour, arising from  the great and  almost universal prosperity of

the country". but at the  same time  he allows that wealth had only advanced gradually, and with  no  great

rapidity. The real solution is to be found in the slow rate  of increase in the numbers of the people. Wealth had

indeed grown  slowly, but its growth had nevertheless been more rapid than that  of  population. 

The improvement in the condition of the labourer was thus due  to  an increase in real and not only in nominal

wages. It is true  that  certain articles, such as soap, salt, candles, leather,  fermented  liquors, had, chiefly owing

to the taxes laid on them,  become a good  deal dearer, and were consumed in very small  quantities; but the

enhanced prices of these things were more  than counterbalanced by the  greater cheapness of grain, potatoes,

turnips, carrots, cabbages,  apples, onions, linen and woollen  cloth, instruments made of the  coarser metals,

and household  furniture. Wheaten bread had largely  superseded rye and barley  bread, which were 'looked

upon with a sort  of horror.' wheat  being as cheap as rye and barley had been in former  times. Every  poor

family drank tea once a day at least  a 'pernicious  commodity,' a 'vile superfluity,' in Arthur Young's eyes.

Their  consumption of meat was 'pretty considerable'; that of cheese was  'immense.' In 1737 the daylabourers

of England, 'by their large  wages and cheapness of all necessaries,' enjoyed better  dwellings,  diet, and apparel

in England, than the husbandmen or  farmers did in  other countries.' The middle of the eighteenth  century was

indeed  about his best time, though a decline soon set  in. By 1771 his  condition had already been somewhat

affected by  the dear years  immediately preceding, when prices had risen much  faster than wages,  although

the change had as yet, according to  Young, merely cut off his  superfluous expenditure. By the end of  the

century men had begun to  look back with regret upon this  epoch in the history of the  agricultural labourer as

one of a  vanished prosperity. At no time  since the passing of the 43d of  Elizabeth, wrote Eden in 1796, 'could

the labouring classes  acquire such a portion of the necessaries and  conveniences of  life by a day's work, as

they could before the late  unparalleled  advance in the price of the necessaries of life.' 

Nor were high wages and cheap food their only advantages.  Their  cottages were often rentfree, being built

upon the waste.  Each  cottage had its piece of ground attached, though the piece  was often a  very small one,

for the Act of Elizabeth, providing  that every cottage  should have four acres of land, was doubtless

unobserved, and was  repealed in 1775. Their common rights,  besides providing fuel, enabled  them to keep


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VI. England in 1760 19



Top




Page No 22


cows and pigs and  poultry on the waste, and sheep on the  fallows and stubbles. But  these rights were already

being steadily  curtailed, and there was  'an open war against cottages.' consequent on  the tendency to

consolidate holdings into large sheepfarms. It was  becoming  customary, too, for unmarried labourers to be

boarded in the  farmers' houses. 

On the whole, the agricultural labourer, at any rate in the  south  of England, was much better off in the middle

of the  eighteenth  century than his descendants were in the middle of the  nineteenth. At  the later date wages

were actually lower in  Suffolk, Essex, and  perhaps parts of Wilts, than they were at the  former; in Berks they

were exactly the same; in Norfolk, Bucks,  Gloucestershire, and South  Wilts, there had been a very trifling

rise; with the exception of  Sussex and Oxfordshire, there was no  county south of the Trent in  which they had

risen more than  onefourth. Meanwhile rent and most  necessaries, except bread,  had increased enormously in

cost, while  most of the labourer's  old privileges were lost, so that his real  wages had actually  diminished. But

in the manufacturing districts of  the north his  condition had improved. While nominal wages in the south  had

risen on the average 14 per cent., here they had risen on the  average 66 per cent. In some districts the rise had

been as great  as  200 per cent. In Arthur Young's time the agricultural wages of  Lancashire were 4s. 6d.  the

lowest rate in England; in 1821  they  had risen to 14s. It may be roughly said that the relative  positions  of the

labourer north and south of the Trent had been  exactly reversed  in the course of a century. 

In Arthur Young's time the highest wages were to be found in  Lincolnshire, the East Riding, and, following

close upon these,  the  metropolitan and eastern counties. At first sight the high  rate of  wages in the first two

counties seems to contradict the  general law  about their relative condition in north and south.  But on

investigation we find it to be due to exceptional  circumstances.  Arguing on the deductive method, we should

conjecture a large demand  for or a small supply of labour; and,  in fact, we find both these  influences in

operation. The  population had actually diminished, in  Lincolnshire from 64 to 58  to the square mile, in the

East Riding,  from 80 to 71; this was  partly due to the enclosures and the  conversion of arable to  pasture,

partly to the increase of  manufactures in the West  Riding. Thus the labourers had been drawn off  to the latter

at  the same time that they were being driven out of the  agricultural  districts. And for the remaining labourers

there was a  great  demand in public works, such as turnpikeroads and agricultural  improvements on a large

scale. 

But there were many local variations of wages which are far  less  easy to bring under the ordinary rules of

Political Economy,  There was  often the greatest inequality in the same county. In  Lincolnshire, for  instance,

wages varied from 12s. 3d. to 7s.,  and even 6s. It was at  this very time that Adam Smith, arguing  deductively

from his primary  axiom that men follow their  pecuniary interest, enunciated the law  that wages tend to an

equality in the same neighbourhood and the same  occupation. Why  then these variations? Adam Smith

himself partly  supplies the  answer. His law pretends to exactness only 'when society  is left  to the natural

course of things.' Now this was impossible when  natural tendencies were diverted by legal restrictions on the

movement of labour, such as the law of settlement, which resulted  in  confining every labourer to his own

parish. But we must not  seek the  cause of these irregularities of wages merely in legal  restrictions.  Apart from

disturbing influences such as this, men  do not always act  in accordance with their pecuniary interest;  there are

other  influences at work affecting their conduct. One  of the strongest of  these is attachment to locality. It was

this  influence which partly  frustrated the recent efforts of the  Labourers' Union to remove the  surplus labour

of the east and  south to the north. Again, there are  apathy and ignorance,  factors of immense importance in

determining the  action of the  uneducated majority of men. In 1872 there were labourers  in Devon  who had

never heard of Lancashire, where they might have been  earning double their own wages. Human beings, as

Adam Smith says,  are  'of all baggage the most difficult to be transported,' though  their  comparative mobility

depends upon the degree of their  education, the  state of communications, and the industrial  conditions of any

particular time. The English labourer today is  far more easy to move  than he was a hundred years ago. In a

stirring new country like  America there is much more mobility of  labour than in England. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VI. England in 1760 20



Top




Page No 23


Turning from the agricultural wageearners to those engaged  in  manufactures, we find their condition at this

period on the  whole much  inferior to what it is now, in spite of the widening  gulf between  capitalist and

labourer, the status of the artisan  has distinctly  improved since Adam Smith's time. His nominal  wages have

doubled or  trebled. A carpenter then earned 2s. 6d. a  day; he now earns 5s. 6d. A  cotton weaver then earned

5s. a week,  he now earns 20s., and so on.  But it is difficult to compare the  condition of the artisan as a whole

at the two periods, because  so many entirely new classes of workmen  have come into existence  during the

past century; for instance, the  engineers, whose Union  now includes 50,000 men earning from 25s. to  40s. a

week. And if  wages have on the whole very greatly increased,  there were, on  the other hand, some obvious

advantages which the  artisan  possessed in those days, but has since lost. For the  manufacturing population

still lived to a very great extent in  the  country. The artisan often had his small piece of land, which  supplied

him with wholesome food and healthy recreation. His  wages and  employment too were more regular. He was

not subject to  the  uncertainties and knew nothing of the fearful sufferings  which his  descendants were to

endure from commercial  fluctuations, especially  before the introduction of free trade.  For the whole inner life

of  industry was, as we have seen,  entirely different from what it now is.  The relation between the  workmen

and their employers was much closer,  so that in many  industries they were not two classes but one. As among

the  agriculturists the farmer and labourer lived much the same  lifefor the capitalist farmers as a class were

not yet in  existenceand ate at the same board, so in manufacturing  industries  the journeyman was often on

his way to become a  master. The  distribution of wealth was, indeed, in all respects  more equal. Landed

property, though gradually being concentrated,  was still in a far  larger number of hands, and even the great

landlords possessed nothing  like their present riches. They had  no vast mineral wealth, or rapidly  developing

town property. A  great number of the trading industries,  too, were still in the  hands of small capitalists. Great

trades, like  the iron trade,  requiring large capital, had hardly come into  existence. 

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith

The contrast between the industrial England of 1760 and the  industrial England of today is not only one of

external  conditions.  Side by side with the revolution which the  intervening century has  effected in the

methods and organisation  of production, there has  taken place a change no less radical in  men's economic

principles, and  in the attitude of the State to  individual enterprise. England in 1760  was still to a great  extent

under the medieval system of minute and  manifold  industrial regulations. That system was indeed decaying,

but  it  had not yet been superseded by the modern principle of industrial  freedom. To understand the origin of

the medieval system we must  go  back to a time when the State was still conceived of as a  religious  institution

with ends that embraced the whole of human  life. In an age  when it was deemed the duty of the State to

watch  over the individual  citizen in all his relations, and provide not  only for his protection  from force and

fraud, but for his eternal  welfare, it was but natural  that it should attempt to insure a  legal rate of interest, fair

wages,  honest wares. Things of vital  importance to man's life were not to be  left to chance or  selfinterest to

settle. For no philosophy had as  yet identified  God and Nature: no optimistic theory of the world had

reconciled  public and private interest. And at the same time, the  smallness  of the world and the community,

and the comparative  simplicity of  the social system made the attempt to regulate the  industrial  relations of

men less absurd than it would appear to us in  the  present day. 

This theory of the State, and the policy of regulation and  restriction which sprang from it, still largely

affected English  industry at the time when Adam Smith wrote. There was, indeed,  great  freedom of internal

trade; there were no provincial  customsbarriers  as in contemporary France and Prussia. Adam  Smith singled

out this  fact as one of the main causes of English  prosperity, and to Colbert  and Stein, and other admirers of

the  English system, such freedom  appeared as an ideal to be  constantly striven after. But though  internal trade

was free for  the passage of commodities, yet there  still existed a network of  restrictions on the mobility of

labour and  capital. By the law of  apprenticeship no person could follow any trade  till he had  served his seven

years. The operation of the law was  limited, it  is true, to trades already established in the fifth year  of

Elizabeth, and obtained only in markettowns and cities. But  wherever there was a municipal corporation, the


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith 21



Top




Page No 24


restrictions  which  they imposed made it generally impossible for a man to work  unless he  was a freeman of

the town, and this he could as a rule  become only by  serving his apprenticeship. Moreover, the  corporations

supervised the  prices and qualities of wares. In the  halls, where the smaller  manufacturers sold their goods,

all  articles exposed for sale were  inspected. The medieval idea still  obtained that the State should  guarantee

the genuineness of  wares: it was not left to the consumer to  discover their quality.  And in the Middle Ages,

no doubt, when men  used the same things  from year to year, a proper supervision did  secure good work. But

with the expansion of trade it ceased to be  effective. Sir Josiah  Child already recognised that changes of

fashion  must prove fatal  to it, and that a nation which intended to have the  trade of the  world must make

articles of every quality. Yet the belief  in the  necessity of regulation was slow in dying out, and fresh Acts  to

secure it were passed as late as George II's reign. 

It is not clear how far the restrictions on the mobility of  capital and Labour were operative. No doubt they

succeeded to a  large  extent; but when Adam Smith wrote his bitter criticism of  the  corporations, he was

probably thinking of the particular  instance of  Glasgow, where Watt was not allowed to set up trade.  There

were,  however, even at that time, many free towns, Like  Birmingham and  Manchester, which flourished

greatly from the fact  of their freedom.  And even in the chartered towns, if Eden is to  be trusted, the

restrictions were far less stringent than we  should gather from Adam  Smith. 'I am persuaded,' he says, 'that a

shoemaker, who had not  served an apprenticeship, might exercise  his industry at Bristol or  Liverpool, with as

little hazard of  being molested by the corporation  of either place, as of being  disturbed by the boroughreve

of  Manchester or the headconstable  at Birmingham.' Then after quoting  and criticising Adam Smith, he

adds: 'I confess, I very much doubt  whether there is a single  corporation in England, the exercise of  whose

rights does at  present operate in this manner.... In this  instance, as in many  others, the insensible progress of

society has  reduced chartered  rights to a state of inactivity.' We may probably  conclude that  nonfreemen were

often unmolested, but that, when trade  was bad,  they were liable to be expelled. 

Another relic of Medievalism was the regulation of wages by  Justices of the Peace, a practice enjoined by the

Act of  Elizabeth  already referred to. Adam Smith speaks of it as part of  a general  system of oppression of the

poor by the rich. Whatever  may have been  the case in some instances this was not generally  true. The country

gentry were, on the whole, anxious to do  justice to the working  classes. Combinations of labourers were

forbidden by law, because it  was thought to be the wrong way of  obtaining the object in view, not  from any

desire to keep down  wages. The Justices often ordained a rise  in wages, and the  workmen themselves were

strongly in favour of this  method of  fixing them. The employers on their part also often approved  of  it. In fact

we have an exactly similar system at the present day  in boards of arbitration. The Justice was an arbitrator,

appointed by  law; and it is a mistaken assumption that such  authoritative  regulation may not have been good

in its day. 

The principle of regulation was applied much more thoroughly  to  our externaL than to our internal trade. The

former was  entirely  carried on by great chartered companies, whether they  were on a  jointstock footing,

Like the East India Company, or  were 'regulated'  like the Turkey Company, in which every man  traded on his

own capital.  Here, again, Adam Smith carried too  far his revolt against the  restrictive system, which Led him

to  denounce corporate trading as  vicious in principle. 'The  directors of such companies,' he says,  'being the

managers rather  of other people's money than of their own,  it cannot well be  expected that they should watch

over it with the  same anxious  vigilance with which the partners in a private  copartnery  frequently watch

over their own.... Negligence and  profusion must  always prevail, more or less, in the management of the

affairs of  such a company.' This is an instance of pure a Priori  reasoning,  but Smith's main argument is

derived from the history of  JointStock Companies. He sought to show that, as a matter of  fact,  unless they

had had a monopoly, they had failed; that is,  he proceeded  inductively, and wound up with an empirical law:

'it  seems contrary to  all experience that a JointStock Company  should be able to carry on  successfully any

branch of foreign  trade, when private adventurers can  come into any sort of open  and fair competition with

them.' But he was  too honest not to  admit exceptions to his rule, as in the instance of  banking,  which he

explained by the fact that it could be reduced to  routine. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith 22



Top




Page No 25


Smith's empirical law is, as we all now know, far from being  universally true, though it was a reasonable

induction enough at  the  time when it was made. Since then a large number of  JointStock  Companies have

succeeded, as for instance in the iron  trade. Nor is it  difficult to see the reason of this change. The  habit of

combination  is stronger than it was, and we have  discovered how to interest paid  servants by giving them a

share  in the results of the enterprises they  direct. Experience has  shown also that a big company can buy the

best  brains. In the  recent depression of trade the ironworks of Dowlais,  which are  managed on the Jointstock

system, alone remained successful  amid  many surrounding failures, and that because they had the ablest  man

in the district as manager. 

In Adam Smith's time, however, the existence of JointStock  Companies was due not to any notion of their

economical  superiority,  but to the tendency to place restrictions upon  individual enterprise,  based upon that

belief in the antagonism  of public and private  interests which was characteristic of the  time. The same idea of

opposition obtained equally in  international relations. The prosperity  of one country was  thought to be

incompatible with that of another. If  one profited  by trade, it seemed to do so at the expense of its  neighbours.

This theory was the foundation of the mercantile system.  It had  its origin in the spirit of Nationalism  the

idea of  selfsustained and complete national life  which came in with  the  Renaissance and the Reformation. 

But how came this Nationalism to he connected with a belief  in the  special importance of gold and silver,

which is generally  regarded as  the essence of the mercantile system? The object of  that system was  national

greatness, but national greatness  depends on national riches  generally, not on one particular kind  of riches

only, such as coin.  The explanation must be sought in  the fact that, owing to the  simultaneous development of

trade and  the money system, gold and  silver became peculiarly essential to  the machinery of commerce. With

the growth of standing armies,  moreover, State finance acquired a new  importance, and the object  of State

finance was to secure a ready  supply of the precious  metals. Thus the theory sprang up that gold and  silver

were the  most solid and durable parts of the moveable wealth of  a nation,  and that, as they had more value in

use than any other  commodities, every state should do all in its power to acquire a  great store of them. At first

the Government tried to attain this  object by accumulating a hoard; but this policy soon proved too  wasteful

and difficult. It then turned its attention to  increasing  the quantity of bullion in the hands of the people,  for it

came to see  that if there was plenty of bullion in the  country it could always  draw upon it in case of need. The

export  of gold and silver was  accordingly forbidden; but if hoarding had  proved impracticable, this  new

method of securing the desired end  was soon found to be useless,  as the prohibition could be easily  evaded. In

the last resort,  therefore, it was sought to insure a  continuous influx of the precious  metals through the

ordinary  channels of trade. If we bought less than  we sold, it was argued,  the balance of trade must be paid in

coin. To  accomplish this end  every encouragement was given to the importation  of raw materials  and the

necessaries of life, but the purchase of  foreign  manufactures was, for the most part, prohibited, and

individuals  were entreated not to buy imported luxuries. The result  was  retaliation abroad, and a deadlock in

the commercial machine.  Wars of tariff were common; for instance, we prohibited the  importation of

goldlace from Flanders, and the Flemings in  return  excluded our wool. The system, however, resisted the

teaching of  experience, despite the fact that in abolishing the  prohibition of the  export of gold and silver, the

Government  acknowledged the true  principle of free trade put forward by the  East Indian Company. The

latter contended that the law forbidding  the export of bullion was not  only useless, since it was easily

stultified by smuggling, but even,  if enforced, was hurtful,  since the Orientals would only sell their  valuable

goods for  silver. The success of this contention marks the  transition from  the Mercantile System proper to

modern Protection. The  advocates  of that system had shifted their ground, and instead of  seeking  merely to

prohibit the export of the precious metals, they  established a general protection of native industries. 

Their measures were not all alike bad. The Navigation Acts,  for  instance, were defended by Adam Smith, and

Mill has indorsed  his  defence, on the ground that national defence is more  important than  national opulence. 

The most famous of these Acts was the law of 1651, by which  no  goods of the growth or manufacture of

Asia, Africa, or America  were to  be imported into England, Ireland, or the Plantations,  except in ships


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith 23



Top




Page No 26


belonging to English subjects, and manned by a  crew threefourths of  whom were English; while no goods of

any  country in Europe were to be  imported except in English ships, or  ships belonging to the country  from

which the goods came. The  argument used by the promoters of the  law was that by excluding  the Dutch from

the carrying trade to this  country we should throw  it into the hands of English shipowners, and  there would he

an  increase of English ships. It was admitted, indeed,  that this  would be giving a monopoly to English

shipowners and English  sailors, and that therefore freights would be dearer, and a check  given to the growth

of commerce. It was further admitted that  owing  to their higher charges English ships might be driven out  of

neutral  ports; but the contention was, that we should secure  to ourselves the  whole of the carrying trade

between America and  the West Indies and  England, and that this would amply compensate  for our expulsion

from  other branches of commerce. 

These anticipations were on the whole fulfilled. The price of  freights was raised, because English ships cost

more to build and  man  than Dutch ships, and thus the total amount of our trade was  diminished. We were

driven out of neutral ports, and lost the  Russian  and the Baltic trades, because the English shipowners, to

whom we had  given a monopoly, raised their charge. But on the  other hand, we  monopolised the trade to

ports coming within the  scope of the Act, the  main object of which was 'the preservation  of our plantation

trade  entire.' Our shipping received a great  stimulus, and our maritime  supremacy grew with it. At the time

when the Navigation Act was passed  our colonial trade was  insignificant; New York and Jersey were Dutch;

Georgia, the  Carolinas, Pennsylvania, Nova Scotia were not yet  planted;  Virginia, Maryland, New England

were in their infancy. At the  end  of the century the Barbados alone employed 400 vessels; while  with the

growth of the colonies the English power at sea had  increased, until it rivalled the Dutch. In the next century

the  continuous development of the American and East Indian trades  gave us  a position of unquestionable

maritime superiority. 

There is another argument in favour of Protection, at any  rate in  its early days. Its stimulus helped to

overcome the  apathy and dulness  of a purely agricultural population, and draw  a part of the people  into trade.

But here, as everywhere,  Protection involves this great  disadvantage, that, once given, it  is difficult to

withdraw, and thus  in the end more harm is done  than good. English industries would not  have advanced so

rapidly  without Protection, but the system, once  established, led to  perpetual wrangling on the part of rival

industries, and  sacrificed India and the colonies to our great  manufacturers. And  our national dislike to

Protection deepens into  repugnance when  we examine the details of the system. Looking at its  results  during

the period from 1688 to 1776, when it was in full  force,  we are forced to acknowledge that Adam Smith's

invectives  against  the merchants, violent as they were, were not stronger than  the  facts demanded. 

But the maintenance of Protection cannot be entirely set down  to  the merchants. Though the trading classes

acquired much  influence at  the Revolution, the landed gentry were still supreme  in Parliament;  and the

question arises, why they should have lent  themselves to a  policy which in many cases, as in the prohibition

of the export of  wool, was distinctly opposed to the interests of  agriculture. Adam  Smith's explanation is very

simple. The country  gentleman, who was  naturally 'least subject of all people to the  wretched spirit of

monopoly,' was imposed upon by the 'clamours  and sophistry of  merchants and manufacturers,' and 'the

sneaking  arts of underling  tradesmen,' who persuaded him into a simple but  honest conviction that  their

interest and not his was the  interest of the public. Now this is  true, but it is not the whole  truth. The

landowners, no doubt, thought  it their duty to protect  trade, and, not understanding its details,  they implicitly

followed the teaching of the merchants. But, besides  this, there  was the close connection, already referred to,

between  them and  the commercial classes. Their younger sons often went into  trade;  they themselves, in

many cases, married merchants' daughters.  Nor  did they give their support gratuitously. they wanted

Protection  for themselves, and if they acquiesced in the prohibition of the  wool  export, they persuaded the

merchants to allow them in return  a bounty  of 5s. a quarter on the export of corn. 

One of the worst features of the system was the struggle of  rival  interests at home. A great instance of this

was the war  between the  woollen and cotton trades, in which the former,  supported by the  landed interest, for


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith 24



Top




Page No 27


a long time had the upper  hand, so that an excise  duty was placed on printed calicoes, and  in 1721 they were

forbidden  altogether. It was not till 1774 that  they were allowed again, and the  excise duty was not repealed

till 1831. To take another instance: it  was proposed in  Parliament in 1750 to allow the importation of pig and

bar iron  from the colonies. The tanners at once petitioned against it,  on  the ground that if American iron was

imported, less iron would be  smelted in England, fewer trees would be cut down, and therefore  their own

industry would suffer; and the owners of woodland  tracts  supported the tanners, lest the value of their timber

should be  affected. These are typical examples of the way in  which, under a  protective system, politics are

complicated and  degraded by the  intermixture of commercial interests. And the  freer a government is,  and the

more exposed to pressure on the  part of its subjects, the  worse will be the result. As an  American observer

has lately said,  Protection may be well enough  under a despotism, but in a republic it  can never be successful. 

We find still stronger illustration of the evils of  Protection in  our policy towards Ireland and the colonies.

After  the Cromwellian  settlement, there had been an export of Irish  cattle into England;  'but for the pacifying

of our landed  gentlemen,' after the Restoration  the import of Irish live stock,  meat and dairy produce was

prohibited  from 1660 to 1685. As  cattlefarming then became unprofitable, the  Irish turned their  lands into

sheepwalks, and not only exported wool,  but started  woollen manufactures at home. Immediately a law was

passed  (1699)  confining the export of Irish wool to the English market; and  this was followed by the

imposition of prohibitive duties on  their  woollen manufactures. The English manufacturers argued that  as

Ireland  was protected by England, and its prosperity was due  to English  capital, the Irish ought to reconcile

themselves to  restrictions on  their trade, in the interests of Englishmen.  Besides, the joint  interests of both

kingdoms would be best  considered if England and  Ireland respectively monopolised the  woollen and linen

industries, and  the two nations thus became  dependent on one another. If we turn to  the colonies, we find

them regarded simply as markets and farms of the  mother country.  The same argument was used: that they

owed everything  to England,  and therefore it was no tyranny to exploit them in her  interests.  They were,

therefore, not allowed to export or import in  any but  British vessels; they might not export such commodities

as  Englishmen wanted to any part of Europe other than Great Britain;  while those of their raw materials in

which our landowners feared  competition were excluded from the English markets. All imports  into  the

colonies from other parts of Europe, except Great  Britain, were  forbidden, in order that our manufacturers

might  monopolise the  American market. Moreover, every attempt was made  to prevent them from  starting

any manufactures at home. At the  end of the seventeenth  century some Americans had set on foot a  woollen

industry'. In 1719 it  was suppressed; all iron  manufactureseven nailmakingwere forbidden;  a flourishing

hat  manufacture had sprung up, but at the petition of  English  hatters, these competitors were not allowed to

export to  England,  or even from one colony to another. Adam Smith might well  say,  that 'to found a great

empire, for the sole purpose of raising up  a people of customers, may at first sight appear a project fit  only  for

a nation of shopkeepers.' Nothing contributed more than  this  commercial system to the Declaration of

independence, and it  is  significant that the same year which saw its promulgation saw  also the  publication of

the Wealth of Nations. 

Many people on first reading the Wealth of Nations are  disappointed. They come to it expecting lucid

arguments, the  clear  exposition of universal laws; they find much tedious and  confused  reasoning and a mass

of facts of only temporary  interest. But these  very defects contributed to its immediate  success. It was

because Adam  Smith examined in detail the actual  conditions of the age, and wrote a  handbook for the

statesman,  and not merely, as Turgot did, a  systematised treatise for the  philosopher, that he appealed so

strongly to the practical men of  his time, who, with Pitt, praised his  'extensive knowledge of  detail,' as well as

'the depth of his  philosophical research.' It  was the combination of the two which gave  him his power. He was

the first great writer on the subject; with him  political economy  passed from the exchange and the

marketplace to the  professor's  study; but he was only groping his way, and we cannot  expect to  meet with

neat arrangement and scientific precision of  treatment  in his book. His language is tentative, he sometimes

makes  distinctions which he forgets elsewhere, as was inevitable before  the  language of economics had been

fixed by endless verbal  discussions. He  had none of Ricardo's power of abstract  reasoning. His gift lay in the

extent and quickness of his  observation, and in his wonderful felicity  of illustration. We  study him because in


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith 25



Top




Page No 28


him, as in Plato, we come  into contact with  a great original mind, which teaches us how to think  and work. 

Original people always are confused because they are feeling  their  way. 

If we look for the fundamental ideas of Adam Smith, those  which  distinguish him most clearly from earlier

writers, we are  first struck  by his cosmopolitanism. He was the precursor of  Cobden in his belief  that

commerce is not of one nation, but that  all the nations of the  world should be considered as one great

community. We may see how  widely he had departed from the old  national system of economy, by

contrasting the mere title of his  book, The Wealth of Nations, with  that of Mun's treatise,  England's Treasure

in Foreign Trade. This  cosmopolitanism  necessitated a detailed refutation of the mercantile  system. He  had to

prove that gold and silver were not more important  than  other forms of wealth; and that if we wanted to buy

them, we  could always do so, if we had other consumable goods to offer in  exchange. But it might be

objected: 'What if a nation refuses to  take  your other goods, and wants your gold?' Adam Smith replied:  'in

that  case, gold will leave your country and go abroad; as a  consequence,  prices will fall at home, foreigners

will be  attracted by the low  prices to buy in your markets, and thus the  gold will return.' I can  give you an

actual example from recent  history to prove the truth of  his deduction. During the potato  famine of 1847, we

had to import  enormous quantities of grain  from America, and as a consequence had to  send there

£16,000,000  worth of bullion. Immediately prices rose in  America and fell in  England, English merchants

discontinued buying in  America, while  American merchants bought largely in England, so that  in the

following year all the gold came back again. 

Equally prominent in Adam Smith is his individualism, his  complete  and unhesitating trust in individual

selfinterest. He  was the first  to appeal to selfinterest as a great bond of  society. As a keen  observer, he

could point to certain facts,  which seemed to bear out  his creed. If we once grant the  principle of the division

of labour,  then it follows that one man  can live only by finding out what other  men want; it is on this  fact, for

instance, that the food supply of  London depends. This  is the basis of the doctrine of laisser faire. It  implies

competition, which would result, so Adam Smith believed, in  men's  wants being supplied at a minimum of

cost. In upholding  competition he was radically opposed to the older writers, who  thought it a hateful thing;

but his conclusion was quite true.  Again  it implies the best possible distribution of industry; for  under a

system of free competition, every man will carry on his  trade in the  locality most suitable for it. 

But the principle of laisser faire breaks down in certain  points  not recognised by Adam Smith. It fails, for

instance, in  assuming that  it is the interest of the producer to supply the  wants of the consumer  in the best

possible manner, that it is the  interest of the producer  to manufacture honest wares. It is quite  true that this is

his  interest, where the trade is an  oldestablished one and has a  reputation to maintain, or where  the

consumer is intelligent enough to  discover whether a  commodity is genuine or not. But these conditions  exist

only to a  small extent in modern commerce. The trade of the  present day is  principally carried on with

borrowed capital; and it  may be a  clever man's interest to sell as large a quantity of goods as  possible in a few

years and then throw up his business. Thus the  interests of producer and consumer conflict, and it has been

found  necessary to pass Adulteration Acts, which recognise the  nonidentity  of interest of seller and buyer. It

was argued,  indeed, in Parliament,  when these acts were proposed, that  consumers ought to take care of

themselves, but the consumers are  far too ignorant to do so,  especially the poor who are the great  consumers

of the articles  protected against adulteration. Adam  Smith, moreover, could not  foresee that internal free trade

might  result in natural monopolies. A  conspicuous feature of our times  is the concentration of certain

industries in the hands of a few  great capitalists, especially in  America, where such rings  actually dictate the

prices of the market.  Eightyfive per cent.  of the Pennsylvania coalmines, for instance,  are in the hands of

six or seven companies who act in combination. The  easiest remedy  for such monopolies would be

international free trade;  with  international competition few could be maintained. Finally, in  the distribution of

wealth there must necessarily be a permanent  antagonism of interests. Adam Smith himself saw this, when he

said  that the rate of wages depended on contracts between two  parties whose  interests were not identical. This

being granted,  we see that in  distribution the 'harmony' of the individual and  the public good is a  figment. At


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith 26



Top




Page No 29


the present day each class of  workmen cares only for the  wages of its own members. Hence the  complete

breakdown of the laisser  faire system in the question of  wages. We have been driven to attempt  the

establishment of Boards  of Conciliation all over the country, thus  virtually surrendering  the principle. Nor is

it true that  selfinterest tends to supply  all our wants; some of our best  institutions, such as hospitals,  owe

their existence to altruistic  sentiment. These antagonisms  were to come out more strongly than ever  after

Adam Smith's time.  There were dark patches even in his age, but  we now approach a  darker perioda period

as disastrous and as terrible  as any  through which a nation ever passed; disastrous and terrible,  because, side

by side with a great increase of wealth was seen an  enormous increase of pauperism; and production on a vast

scale,  the  result of free competition, led to a rapid alienation of  classes and  to the degradation of a large body

of producers. 

VIII. The Chief Features of the Revolution

The essence of the industrial Revolution is the substitution  of  competition for the medieval regulations which

had previously  controlled the production and distribution of wealth. On this  account  it. IS not only one of the

most important facts of  English history,  but Europe owes to it the growth of two great  systems of thought 

Economic Science, and its antithesis,  Socialism. The development of  Economic Science in England has  four

chief landmarks, each connected  with the name of one of the  four great English economists. The first  is the

publication of  Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations in 1776, in which  he investigated  the causes of wealth and

aimed at the substitution of  industrial  freedom for a system of restriction. The production of  wealth,  not the

welfare of man, was what Adam Smith had primarily  before  his mind's eye; in his own words, 'the great

object of the  Political Economy of every country is to increase the riches and  power of that country.' His great

book appeared on the eve of the  industrial Revolution. A second stage in the growth of the  science is  marked

by Malthus's Essay on Population, published in  1798, which may  be considered the product of that

revolution,  then already in full  swing. Adam Smith had concentrated all his  attention on a large  production;

Malthus directed his inquiries,  not to the causes of  wealth but to the causes of poverty, and  found them in his

theory of  population. A third stage is marked  by Ricardo's Principles of  Political Economy and Taxation,

which  appeared in 1817, and in which  Ricardo sought to ascertain the  laws of the distribution of wealth.

Adam Smith had shown how  wealth could be produced under a system of  industrial freedom,  Ricardo

showed how wealth is distributed under  such a system, a  problem which could not have occurred to any one

before his time.  The fourth stage is marked by John Stuart Mill's  Principles of  Political Economy, published

in 1848. Mill himself  asserted that  'the chief merit of his treatise' was the distinction  drawn  between the laws

of production and those of distribution, and  the  problem he tried to solve was, how wealth ought to be

distributed. A great advance was made by Mill's attempt to show  what  was and what was not inevitable under

a system of free  competition. In  it we see the influence which the rival system of  Socialism was  already

beginning to exercise upon the economists.  The whole spirit of  Mill's book is quite different from that of  any

economic works which  had up to his time been written in  England. Though a restatement of  Ricardo's

system, it contained  the admission that the distribution of  wealth is the result of  'particular social

arrangements,' and it  recognised that  competition alone is not a satisfactory basis of  society. 

Competition, heralded by Adam Smith, and taken for granted by  Ricardo and Mill, is still the dominant idea

of our time; though  since the publication of the Origin of Species, we hear more of  it  under the name of the

'struggle for existence.' I wish here to  notice  the fallacies involved in the current arguments on this  subject. In

the first place it is assumed that all competition is  a competition  for existence. This is not true. There is a

great  difference between a  struggle for mere existence and a struggle  for a particular kind of  existence. For

instance, twelve men are  struggling for employment in a  trade where there is only room for  eight; four are

driven out of that  trade, but they are not  trampled out of existence. A good deal of  competition merely

decides what kind of work a man is to do; though of  course when a  man can only do one kind of work, it may

easily become a  struggle  for bare life. It is next assumed that this struggle for  existence is a law of nature, and

that therefore all human  interference with it is wrong. To that I answer that the whole  meaning of civilisation


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VIII. The Chief Features of the Revolution 27



Top




Page No 30


is interference with this brute struggle.  We  intend to modify the violence of the fight, and to prevent the  weak

being trampled under foot. 

Competition, no doubt, has its uses. Without competition no  progress would be possible, for progress comes

chiefly from  without;  it is external pressure which forces men to exert  themselves.  Socialists, however,

maintain that this advantage is  gained at the  expense of an enormous waste of human life and  labour, which

might be  avoided by regulation. But here we must  distinguish between  competition in production and

competition in  distribution, a  difference recognised in modern legislation,  which has widened the  sphere of

contract in the one direction,  while it has narrowed it in  the other. For the struggle of men to  outvie one

another in production  is beneficial to the community;  their struggle over the division of  the joint produce is

not. The  stronger side will dictate its own  terms; and as a matter of  fact, in the early days of competition the

capitalists used all  their power to oppress the labourers, and drove  down wages to  starvation point. This kind

of competition has to be  checked;  there is no historical instance of its having lasted long  without  being

modified either by combination or legislation, or both.  In  England both remedies are in operation, the former

through Trades  Unions, the latter through factory legislation. In the past other  remedies were applied. It is

this desire to prevent the evils of  competition that affords the true explanation of the fixing of  wages  by

Justices of the Peace, which seemed to Ricardo a remnant  of the old  system of tyranny in the interests of the

strong.  Competition, we have  now learnt, is neither good nor evil in  itself; it is a force which  has to be studied

and controlled; it  may be compared to a stream whose  strength and direction have to  be observed, that

embankments may be  thrown up within which it  may do its work harmlessly and beneficially.  But at the

period we  are considering it came to be believed in as a  gospel, and, the  idea of necessity being superadded,

economic laws  deduced from  the assumption of universal unrestricted competition were  converted into

practical precepts, from which it was regarded as  little short of immoral to depart. 

Coming to the facts of the Industrial Revolution, the first  thing  that strikes us is the far greater rapidity which

marks the  growth of  population. Before 1751 the largest decennial increase,  so far as we  can calculate from

our imperfect materials, was 3  per cent. For each  of the next three decennial periods the  increase was 6 per

cent.; then  between 1781 and 1791 it was 9 per  cent.; between 1791 and 1801, 11  per cent.; between 1801

and  1811, 14 per cent.; between 1811 and 182l,  18 per cent. This is  the highest figure ever reached in

England, for  since 1815 a vast  emigration has been always tending to moderate it;  between 1815  and 1880

over eight millions (including Irish) have left  our  shores. But for this our normal rate of increase would be 16

or  18 instead of 12 per cent. In every decade. 

Next we notice the relative and positive decline in the  agricultural population. In 1811 it constituted 35 per

cent. of  the  whole population of Great Britain; in 1821, 33 per cent.; in  1831, 28  per cent. And at the same

time its actual numbers have  decreased. In  1831 there were 1,243,057 adult males employed in  agriculture in

Great  Britain; in 1841 there were 1,207,989. In  1851 the whole number of  persons engaged in agriculture in

England was 2,084,153; in 1861 it  was 2,010,454, and in 1871 it  was 1,657,138. Contemporaneously with

this change, the centre of  density of population has shifted from the  Midlands to the North;  there are at the

present day 458 persons to the  square mile in  the counties north of the Trent, as against 312 south  of the

Trent. And we have lastly to remark the change in the relative  population of England and Ireland. Of the total

population of the  three kingdoms, Ireland had in 1821 32 per cent., in 1881 only  14.6  per cent. 

An agrarian revolution plays as large part in the great  industrial  change of the end of the eighteenth century as

does  the revolution in  manufacturing industries, to which attention is  more usually directed.  Our next inquiry

must therefore be: What  were the agricultural changes  which led to this noticeable  decrease in the rural

population? The  three most effective causes  were: the destruction of the commonfield  system of cultivation;

the enclosure, on a large scale, of common and  waste lands; and  the consolidation of small 'farms into large.

We have  already  seen that while between 1710 and 1760 some 300,000 acres were  enclosed, between 1760

and 1843 nearly 7,000,000 underwent the  same  process. Closely connected with the enclosure system was the

substitution of large for small farms. In the first half of the  century Laurence, though approving of


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VIII. The Chief Features of the Revolution 28



Top




Page No 31


consolidation from an  economic  point of view, had thought that the odium attaching to  an evicting  landlord

would operate as a strong check upon it. But  these scruples  had now disappeared. Eden in 1795 notices how

constantly the change  was effected, often accompanied by the  conversion of arable to  pasture; and relates

how in a certain  Dorsetshire village he found two  farms where twenty years ago  there had been thirty. The

process went  on uninterruptedly into  the present century. Cobbett, writing in 1826,  says: 'In the  parish of

Burghclere one single farmer holds, under Lord  Carnarvon, as one farm, the lands that those now living

remember  to  have formed fourteen farms, bringing up in a respectable way  fourteen  families.' The

consolidation of farms reduced the number  of farmers,  while the enclosures drove the labourers off the  land,

as it became  impossible for them to exist without their  rights of pasturage for  sheep and geese on common

lands. 

Severely, however, as these changes bore upon the rural  population, they wrought, without doubt, distinct

improvement  from an  agricultural point of view. They meant the substitution  of scientific  for unscientific

culture. 'It has been found,' says  Laurence, 'by long  experience, that common or open fields are  great

hindrances to the  public good, and to the honest  improvement which every one might make  of his own.'

Enclosures  brought an extension of arable cultivation and  the tillage of  inferior soils; and in small farms of 40

to 100 acres,  where the  land was exhausted by repeated corn crops, the farm  buildings of  clay and mud walls

and threefourths of the estate often  saturated with water, consolidation into farms of 100 to 500  acres  meant

rotation of crops, leases of nineteen years, and good  farm  buildings. The period was one of great agricultural

advance;  the breed  of cattle was improved, rotation of crops was generally  introduced,  the steamplough was

invented, agricultural societies  were instituted.  In one respect alone the change was injurious.  In consequence

of the  high prices of corn which prevailed during  the French war, some of the  finest permanent pastures were

broken  up. Still, in spite of this, it  was said in 1813 that during the  previous ten years agricultural  produce

had increased by  onefourth, and this was an increase upon a  great increase in the  preceding generation. 

Passing to manufactures, we find here the allprominent fact  to be  the substitution of the factory for the

domestic system,  the  consequence of the mechanical discoveries of the time. Four  great  inventions altered the

character of the cotton manufacture;  the  spinningjenny, patented by Hargreaves in 1770; the  waterframe,

invented by Arkwright the year before; Crompton's  mule introduced in  1779, and the selfacting mule, first

invented  by Kelly in 1792, but  not brought into use till Roberts improved  it in 1825. None of these  by

themselves would have revolutionised  the industry. But in 1769the  year in which Napoleon and  Wellington

were bornJames Watt took out  his patent for the  steamengine. Sixteen years later it was applied to  the

cotton  manufacture. In 1785 Boulton and Watt made an engine for a  cottonmill at Papplewick in Notts, and

in the same year  Arkwright's  patent expired. These two facts taken together mark  the introduction  of the

factory system. But the most famous  invention of all, and the  most fatal to domestic industry, the

powerloom, though also patented  by Cartwright in 1785, did not  come into use for several years, and  till the

powerloom was  introduced the workman was hardly injured. At  first, in fact,  machinery raised the wages of

spinners and weavers  owing to the  great prosperity it brought to the trade. In fifteen  years the  cotton trade

trebled itself; from 1788 to 1803 has been  called  its 'golden age". for, before the powerloom but after the

introduction of the mule and other mechanical improvements by  which  for the first time yarn sufficiently fine

for muslin and a  variety of  other fabrics was spun, the demand became such that  'old barns,  carthouses,

outbuildings of all descriptions were  repaired, windows  broke through the old blank walls, and all  fitted up

for loomshops;  new weavers' cottages with loomshops  arose in every direction, every  family bringing

home weekly from  40 to 12O shillings per week.' At a  later date, the condition of  the workman was very

different.  Meanwhile, the iron industry had  been equally revolutionised by the  invention of smelting by

pitcoal brought into use between 1740 and  1750, and by the  application in 1788 of the steamengine to blast

furnaces. In the  eight years which followed this later date, the  amount of iron  manufactured nearly doubled

itself. 

A further growth of the factory system took place independent  of  machinery, and owed its origin to the

expansion of trade, an  expansion  which was itself due to the great advance made at this  time in the  means of


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VIII. The Chief Features of the Revolution 29



Top




Page No 32


communication. The canal system was being  rapidly developed  throughout the country. In 1777 the Grand

Trunk  canal, 96 miles in  length, connecting the Trent and Mersey, was  finished; Hull and  Liverpool were

connected by one canal while  another connected them  both with Bristol; and in 1792, the Grand  Junction

canal, 90 miles in  length, made a waterway from London  through Oxford to the chief  midland towns. Some

years afterwards,  the roads were greatly improved  under Telford and Macadam;  between 1818 and 1829

more than a thousand  additional miles of  turnpike road were constructed; and the next year,  1830, saw the

opening of the first railroad. These improved means of  communication caused an extraordinary increase in

commerce, and  to  secure a sufficient supply of goods it became the interest of  the  merchants to collect

weavers around them in great numbers, to  get  looms together in a workshop, and to give out the warp

themselves to  the workpeople. To these latter this system meant a  change from  independence to dependence;

at the beginning of the  century the report  of a committee asserts that the essential  difference between the

domestic and the factory system is, that  in the latter the work is  done 'by persons who have no property  in the

goods they manufacture.'  Another direct consequence of  this expansion of trade was the regular  recurrence of

periods of  overproduction and of depression, a  phenomenon quite unknown  under the old system, and due

to this new  form of production on a  large scale for a distant market. 

These altered conditions in the production of wealth  necessarily  involved an equal revolution in its

distribution. In  agriculture the  prominent fact is an enormous rise in rents. Up  to 1795, though they  had risen

in some places, in others they had  been stationary since the  Revolution. But between 1790 and 1833,

according to Porter, they at  least doubled. In Scotland, the  rental of land, which in 1795 had  amounted to

£2,000,000, had  risen in 1815 to £5,27 8,685. A farm in  Essex, which before 1793  had been rented at 10s. an

acre, was let in  1812 at 50s., though,  six years after, this had fallen again to 35s.  In Berks and  Wilts, farms

which in 1790 were let at 14s., were let in  1810 at  70s., and in 1820 at 50s. Much of this rise, doubtless, was

due  to money invested in improvementsthe first Lord Leicester is  said to have expended £400,000 on his

propertybut it was far  more  largely the effect of the enclosure system, of the  consolidation of  farms, and of

the high price of corn during the  French war. Whatever  may have been its causes, however, it  represented a

great social  revolution, a change in the balance of  political power and in the  relative position of classes. The

farmers shared in the prosperity of  the landlords; for many of  them held their farms under beneficial  leases,

and made large  profits by them. In consequence, their  character completely  changed; they ceased to work and

live with their  labourers, and  became a distinct class. The high prices of the war  time  thoroughly demoralised

them, for their wealth then increased so  fast, that they were at a loss what to do with it. Cobbett has  described

the change in their habits, the new food and furniture,  the  luxury and drinking, which were the consequences

of more  money coming  into their hands than they knew how to spend.  Meanwhile, the effect of  all these

agrarian changes upon the  condition of the labourer was an  exactly opposite and most  disastrous one. He felt

all the burden of  high prices, while his  wages were steadily falling, and he had lost  his commonrights.  It is

from this period, viz., the beginning of the  present  century, that the alienation between farmer and labourer

may  be  dated. 

Exactly analogous phenomena appeared in the manufacturing  world.  The new class of great capitalist

employers made enormous  fortunes,  they took little or no part personally in the work of  their factories,  their

hundreds of workmen were individually  unknown to them; and as a  consequence, the old relations between

masters and men disappeared,  and a 'cash nexus' was substituted  for the human tie. The workmen on  their

side resorted to  combination, and TradesUnions began a fight  which looked as if  it were between mortal

enemies rather than joint  producers. 

The misery which came upon large sections of the working  people at  this epoch was often, though not

always, due to a fall  in wages, for,  as I said above, in some industries they rose. But  they suffered  likewise

from the conditions of labour under the  factory system, from  the rise of prices, especially from the high  price

of bread before the  repeal of the cornlaws, and from those  sudden fluctuations of trade,  which, ever since

production has  been on a large scale, have exposed  them to recurrent periods of  bitter distress. The effects of

the  industrial Revolution prove  that free competition may produce wealth  without producing  wellbeing. We


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

VIII. The Chief Features of the Revolution 30



Top




Page No 33


all know the horrors that ensued in  England before  it was restrained by legislation and combination. 

IX. The Growth of Pauperism

Malthus tells us that his book was suggested by Godwin's  Inquiry,  but it was really prompted by the rapid

growth of  pauperism which  Malthus saw around him, and the book proved the  main influence which

determined the reform of the English Poor  Laws. The problem of  pauperism came upon men in its most

terrible  form between 1795 and  1834. The following statistics will  illustrate its growth: 

Year Population    Poorrate          Per head of Population

1760 7,000,000     £1,250,000              or 3s. 7d.

1784 8,000,000     2,000,000               or 5s. 0d.

1803 9,216,000     4,077,000               or 8s. 11d.

1818 11,876,000    7,870,000               or 13s. 3d.

This was the highest rate ever reached. But really to understand  the  nature of the problem we must examine

the previous history of  pauperism, its causes in different periods, and the main  influences  which determined

its increase. 

Prejudices have arisen against Political Economy because it  seemed  to tell men to follow their selfinterest

and to repress  their  instincts of benevolence. Individual selfinterest makes no  provision  for the poor, and to

do so other motives and ideas must  take its  place; hence the idea that Political Economy taught that  no such

provision should be made. Some of the old economists did  actually say  that people should be allowed to die

in the street.  Yet Malthus, with  all his hatred of the Poor Law, thought that  'the evil was now so  deeply

seated, and relief given by the Poor  Laws so widely extended,  that no man of humanity could venture to

propose their immediate  abolition.' The assumed cruelty of  political economy arises from a  mistaken

conception of its  province, and from that confusion of ideas  to which I have before  alluded, which turned

economic laws into  practical precepts, and  refused to allow for the action of other  motives by their side.  What

we now see to be required is not the  repression of the  instincts of benevolence, but their organisation. To

make  benevolence scientific is the great problem of the present age.  Men formerly thought that the simple

direct action of the  benevolent  instincts by means of selfdenying gifts was enough to  remedy the  misery

they deplored; now we see that not only thought  but historical  study is also necessary. Both to understand the

nature of pauperism  and to discover its effectual remedies, we  must investigate its  earlier history. But in

doing this we should  take to heart two  warnings: first, not to interpret medieval  statutes by modern ideas;  and

secondly, not to assume that the  causes of pauperism have always  been the same. 

The history of the Poor Laws divides itself into three  epochs;  from 1349 to 1601, from 1601 to 1782, and

from 1782 to  1834. Now, what  was the nature of pauperism in medieval society,  and what were then  the

means of relieving it? Certain  characteristics are permanent in  all society, and thus in  medieval life as

elsewhere there was a class  of impotent poor,  who were neither able to support themselves nor had  relatives

to  support them. This was the only form of pauperism in the  early  beginnings of medieval society, and it was

provided for as  follows. The community was then broken up into groups  the  manor,  the guild, the family,

the Church with its hospitals, and  each group  was responsible for the maintenance of all its  members; by

these means  all classes of poor were relieved. In the  towns the craft and  religious guilds provided for their

own  members; large estates in land  were given to the guilds, which  'down to the Reformation formed an

organised administration of  relief' ('the religious guilds were  organised for the relief of  distress as well as for

conjoint and  mutual prayer';)  while  outside the guilds there were the churches,  the hospitals, and  the

monasteries. The 'settled poor' in towns were  relieved by the  guilds, in the country by the lords of the manor

and  the  beneficed clergy. 'Every manor had its constitution,' says  Professor Stubbs, and, referring to

manumission, he adds, 'the  native  lost the privilege of maintenance which he could claim of  his lord.'  Among

what were called 'the vagrant poor' there were  the professional  beggars, who were scarcely then considered


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IX. The Growth of Pauperism 31



Top




Page No 34


what  we should now call  paupers, and 'the valiant labourers' wandering  only in search of work.  Who then

were the paupers? In the towns  there were the craftsmen, who  could not procure admission into a  guild. In the

country there was the  small class of landless  labourers nominally free. It is a great law of  social development

that the movement from slavery to freedom is also a  movement from  security to insecurity of maintenance.

There is a close  connection between the growth of freedom and the growth of  pauperism;  it is scarcely too

much to say that the latter is the  price we pay for  the former. The first Statute that is in any  sense a Poor Law

was  enacted at a time when the emancipation of  the serfs was proceeding  rapidly. This is the Statute of

Labourers, made in 1349; it has  nothing to do with the  maintenance of the poor'. Its object was to  repress

their  vagrancy. 

This Statute has been variously interpreted. According to  some, it  was simply an attempt of the landowners to

force the  labourers to take  the old wages of the times before the Plague.  Others object, with  Brentano, to this

interpretation, and believe  that it was not an  instance of class legislation, but merely  expressed the medieval

idea  that prices should be determined by  what was thought reasonable and  not by competition; for this same

Statute regulates the prices of  provisions and almost everything  which was sold at the time. Probably

Brentano is in the main  right. It is true that the landowners did  legislate with the  knowledge that the Statute

would be to their own  advantage; but  the law is none the less in harmony with all the ideas  of the  age. The

Statute affected the labourer in two directions: it  fixed his wages, and it prevented him from migrating. It was

followed  by the Statute of 1388, which is sometimes called the  beginning of the  English Poor Law. We here

find the first  distinction between the  impotent and the ablebodied poor. This  law decreed that if their

neighbours would not provide for the  poor, they were to seek  maintenance elsewhere in the hundred; no  one

is considered responsible  for them; it is assumed that the  people of the parish will support  them. Here too we

catch the  first glimpse of a law of settlement in  the provision that no  labourer or pauper shall wander out of

his  hundred unless he  carry a letterpatent with him. 

No exact date can be assigned to the growth of ablebodied  pauperism. It was the result of gradual social

changes, and of  the  inability to understand them. Medieval legislators could not  grasp the  necessity for the

mobility of labour, nor could they  see that  compulsory provision for the poor was essential, though  the

Statute of  l388 shows that the bond between lord and  dependent was snapped, and  security for their

maintenance in this  way already at an end. The  Church and private charity were deemed  sufficient; though it

is true  that laws were passed to prevent  the alienation of funds destined for  the poor. And with regard to  the

mobility of labour, we must remember  that the vagrancy of the  times did not imply the distress of the

labourers, but their  prosperity. The scarcity of labour allowed of  high wages, and the  vagrant labourer of the

time seems never to have  been satisfied,  but always wandering in search of still higher wages.  The  stability of

medieval society depended on the fixity of all its  parts, as that of modern society is founded on their mobility.

The  Statutes afford evidence that high wages and the destruction  of old  ties did in fact lead to disorder,

robbery and violence;  and by and by  we find the condition of the labourer reversed; in  the next period he  is a

vagrant, because he cannot find work. 

In the sixteenth century pauperism was becoming a really  serious  matter. If we ask, What were its causes

then, and what  the remedies  proposed, we shall find that at the beginning of the  century a great  agrarian

revolution was going on, during which  pauperism largely  increased. Farms were consolidated, and arable

converted into pasture;  in consequence, where two hundred men had  lived there were now only  two or three

herdsmen. There was no  employment for the dispossessed  farmers, who became simple  vagabonds, 'valiant

beggars,' until later  they were absorbed into  the towns by the increase of trade. A main  cause of the agrarian

changes was the dissolution of monasteries,  though it was one  that acted only indirectly, by the monastic

properties passing  into the hands of new men who did not hesitate to  evict without  scruple. About the same

time the prices of provisions  rose  through the influx of the precious metals and the debasement of  the

coinage. And while the prices of corn in 154182 rose 240 per  cent as compared with the past one hundred

and forty years, wages  rose only 160 per cent. In this fact we discover a second great  cause  of the pauperism

of the time; just as at the end of the  eighteenth  century we find wages the last to rise, and the  labouring man


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IX. The Growth of Pauperism 32



Top




Page No 35


the  greatest sufferer from increased prices. As  regards the growth of  pauperism in towns, the main cause may

be  found in the confiscation of  the estates of the guilds by the  Protector Somerset. These guilds had  been

practically friendly  societies, and depended for their funds upon  their landed  properties. 

And how did statesmen then deal with these phenomena? The  legislation of the age about 'vagabonds' is

written in blood. The  only remedy suggested was to punish the vagrant by cruel  torturesby  whipping and

branding. Even death was resorted to  after a second or  third offence; and though these penalties  proved very

ineffectual, the  system was not abandoned till the  law of 43 Elizabeth recognised that  punishment had failed

as a  remedy. The other class of paupers, the  impotent poor, had been  directed by a Statute of Richard II to

beg  within a certain  limited area; in the reigns of Edward VI and  Elizabeth the  necessity of compulsory

provision for this class of poor  slowly  dawned upon men's minds. At first the churchwardens were  ordered  to

summon meetings for the purpose of collecting alms, and  overseers were appointed who 'shall gently ask and

demand' of  every  man and woman what they of their charity will give weekly  towards the  relief of the poor.

Mayors, headofficers, and  churchwardens were to  collect money in boxes 'every Sunday and  holyday.' The

parsons, vicar  and curate, were to reason with  those who would not give, and if they  were not successful, the

obstinate person was to be sent to the  bishop, who was to 'induce  and persuade him'; or by the provisions of  a

later law, he was to  be assessed at Quarter Sessions (1562). Such  was the first  recognition of the principle of

compulsory support, of  the fact  that there are men in the community whom no one will relieve.  There appears

upon the scene for the first time the isolated  individual, a figure unknown to medieval society, but who

constitutes  so striking a phenomenon in the modern world. And  hence springs up a  new relation between the

State and the  individual. Since the latter is  no longer a member of a compact  group, the State itself has to

enter  into direct connection with  him. Thus, by the growth at once of  freedom and of poverty, the  whole

status of the working classes had  been changed, and the  problem of modern legislation came to be this:  to

discover how we  can have a working class of free men, who shall yet  find it easy  to obtain sustenance; in

other words, how to combine  political  and material freedom. 

All the principles of our modern Poor Laws are found in the  next  Statute we have to notice, the great law of

the 43rd year of  Elizabeth, which drew the sharp distinction, ever since  preserved,  between the ablebodied

and the impotent poor. The  latter were to be  relieved by a compulsory rate collected by the  overseers, the

former  were to be set to work upon materials  provided out of the rates;  children and orphans were to be

apprenticed. From this date 1601,  there were no fundamental  changes in the law till the end of the  eighteenth

century. The  law of settlement, however, which sprang  directly out of the Act  of Elizabeth, was added; it was

the first  attempt to prevent the  migration of labourers by other means than  punishment. It began  with the

Statute of 1662, which allowed a pauper  to obtain relief  only from that parish where he had his settlement,

and defined  settlement as forty days' residence without interruption;  but  after this Statute there were constant

changes in the law,  leading to endless complications; and more litigation took place  on  this question of

settlement than on any other point of the  Poor Law.  It was not till 1795 that the hardship of former

enactments was  mitigated by an Act under which no new settler  could be removed until  he became actually

chargeable to the  parish. 

Two other modifications of the Act of Elizabeth require to be  noticed. In 1691 the administration of relief

was partially taken  out  of the hands of the overseers and given to the Justices of  the Peace,  the alleged reason

being that the overseers had abused  their power.  Henceforth they were not allowed to relieve except  by order

of a  Justice of the Peace, and this provision was  construed into a power  conferred upon the Justices to give

relief  independently of any  application on the part of the overseers,  and led, in fact, to  Justices ordering relief

at their own  discretion. The other important  change in the Poor Law was the  introduction of the workhouse

test in  1722. It is clear that  pauperism had grown since the reign of Charles  II. There are many  pamphlets of

the period full of suggestions as to a  remedy, but  the only successful idea was this of the workhouse test.

Parishes  were now empowered to unite and build a workhouse, and refuse  relief to all who would not enter it;

but the clauses for  building  workhouses remained inoperative, as very few parishes  would adopt  them. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IX. The Growth of Pauperism 33



Top




Page No 36


The question remains to be asked: Why was pauperism still  slowly  increasing in the course of the seventeenth

and eighteenth  centuries  in spite of a rise in wages, and, during the first half  of the  eighteenth century, a low

price of corn? Enclosures and  the  consolidation of farms, though as yet these had been on a  comparatively

small scale, were partly responsible for it, as  they  were in an earlier century. Already, in 1727, it was said  that

some  owners were much too eager to evict farmers and  cottagers, and were  punished by an increase of rates

consequent  on the evicted tenants  sinking into pauperism. By Eden's time the  practice of eviction had  become

general, and the connection  between eviction and pauperism is  an indisputable fact, though it  has been

overlooked by most writers.  Eden's evidence again shows  that pauperism was greatest where  enclosures had

taken place. At  Winslow, for instance, enclosed in 1744  and 1766, 'the rise of  the rates was chiefly ascribed

to the enclosure  of the common  fields, which, it was said, had lessened the number of  farms, and  from the

conversion of arable into pasture had much reduced  the  demand for labourers.' Again, at

KilworthBeauchamp in  Leicestershire, 'the fields being now in pasturage, the farmers  had  little occasion for

labourers, and the poor being thereby  thrown out  of employment had, of course, to be supported by the

parish.' Here too  the evil was aggravated by the fate of the  ejected farmers, who sank  into the condition of

labourers, and  swelled the numbers of the  unemployed. 'Living in a state of  servile dependence on the large

farmers, and having no prospect  to which their hopes could reasonably  look forward, their  industry was

checked, economy was deprived of its  greatest  stimulation, and their only thought was to enjoy the present

moment.' Again, at Blandford, where the same consolidation of  farms  had been going on, Eden remarks that

'its effects, it is  said, oblige  small industrious farmers to turn labourers or  servants, who, seeing  no opening

towards advancement, become  regardless of futurity, spend  their little wages as they receive  them without

reserving a pension  for their old age; and, if  incapacitated from working by a sickness  which lasts a very

short  time, inevitably fall upon the parish.' 

Besides the enclosure of the commonfields, and the  consolidation  of farms, the enclosure of the commons

and wastes  likewise contributed  to the growth of pauperism. Arthur Young and  Eden thought that commons

were a cause of idleness; the labourers  wasted their time in gathering  sticks or grubbing furze; their  pigs and

cows involved perpetual  disputes with their neighbours,  and were a constant temptation to  trespass. No doubt

this was  true where the common was large enough to  support the poor  without other occupation. But on the

other hand,  where the  labourer was regularly employed, a small common was a great  extra  resource to him.

Arthur Young himself mentions a case at  Snettisham in Norfolk, where, when the waste was enclosed, the

common  rights had been preserved, and as a result of this,  combined with the  increased labour due to the

enclosure, the  poorrates fell from 1 s.  6d. to 1 s. or 9d., while population  grew from five to six hundred. He

goes on to say that enclosures  had generally been carried out with an  utter disregard for the  rights of the poor.

According to Thornton, the  formation of parks  contributed to the general result, but I know of no  evidence on

this head. A further cause of pauperism, when we come to  the end  of the century, was the great rise in prices

as compared with  that in wages. In 1782 the price of corn was 53s. 9 1/4d., which  was  considerably higher

than the average of the preceding fifty  years; but  in 1795 it had risen to 81s. 6d., and in the next year  it was

even  more. The corn average from 1795 to 1805 was 81s. 2  1/2d., and from  1805 to 1815 97s. 6d. In 1800

and 1801 it reached  the maximum of 127s.  and 128s. 6d., which brought us nearer to a  famine than we had

been  since the fourteenth century. Many other  articles had risen too. The  taxes necessitated by the debt

contracted during the American war  raised the prices of soap,  leather, candles, etc., by onefifth;  butter and

cheese rose 1  1/2d. a pound, meat 1 d. And meanwhile, 'what  advance during the  last ten or twelve years,'

asks a writer in 1788,  'has been made  in the wages of labourers? Very little indeed; in their  daily  labour

nothing at all, either in husbandry or manufactures.'  Only  by piecework could they obtain more in nominal

wages. Lastly, in  the towns there had come the introduction of machinery, the final  establishment of the

cashnexus, and the beginning of great  fluctUations in trade. In the old days the employer maintained  his

men when out of work, now he repudiated the responsibility;  and the  decline in the position of the artisan

could be  attributed by  contemporary writers to 'the iniquitous oppressive  practices of those  who have the

direction of them.' 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IX. The Growth of Pauperism 34



Top




Page No 37


Such seem to have been the causes of the growth of pauperism  and  of the degradation of the labourer; the

single effective  remedy  attempted was the workhouse test, and this was abandoned  in 1782. But  might not

landlords and farmers have done something  more to check the  downward course? Were there no possible

remedies? One cannot help  thinking the problem might have been  solved by common justice in the  matter of

enclosures. Those who  were most in favour of enclosing for  the sake of agricultural  improvements, like Eden

and Young, yet held  that, in place of his  common field and pasture rights, the labourer  should have had an

acre, or two acres, or half an acre, as the case  might be,  attached to his cottage. By such compensation much

misery  would  have been prevented. A more difficult question is, whether  anything could have been done

directly to relieve the stress of  high  prices? Burke contended that nothing could be done, that  there was no

necessary connection between wages and prices; and  he would have left  the evil to natural remedies. And, as

a matter  of fact, in the North  where there was no artificial interference  with wages, the development  of

mining and manufactures saved the  labourer. 

In the Midlands and South, where this needful stimulus was  absent,  the case was different; some increase in

the labourer's  means of  subsistence was absolutely necessary here, in order that  he might  exist. It would have

been dangerous to let things alone;  and the true  way to meet the difficulty would have been for the  farmers to

have  raised wages  a course of action which they have  at times adopted.  But an absence alike of intelligence

and  generosity, and the vicious  working of the Poor Laws in the  midland and southern counties,  prevented

this. The farmers  refused to recognise the claims alike of  humanity and  selfinterest, so the justices and

country gentlemen took  the  matter into their own hands, while the labourers threw themselves  upon the Poor

Law, and demanded that the parish should do what  the  farmers refused to do, and should supplement

insufficient  wages by an  allowance. This was the principle which radically  vitiated the old  Poor Law. The

farmers supported the system; they  wished every man to  have an allowance according to his family,  and

declared that 'high  wages and free labour would overwhelm  them.' A change had also come  over the minds of

the landowners as  to their relation to the people.  In addition to unthinking and  ignorant benevolence, we can

trace the  growth of a sentiment  which admitted an unconditional right on the  part of the poor to  an indefinite

share in the national wealth; but  the right was  granted in such a way as to keep them in dependence and

diminish  their selfrespect. Though it was increased by the panic of  the  French revolution, this idea of

bribing the people into  passiveness was not absolutely, new. It had prompted Gilbert's  Act in  1782, which

abolished the workhouse test, and provided  work for those  who were willing near their homes. It was this

Tory Socialism, this  principle of protection of the poor by the  rich, which gave birth to  the frequent use of the

term 'labouring  poor,' so common in the  Statutes and in Adam Smith, an expression  which Burke attacked as

a  detestable canting phrase. 

The war with Napoleon gave a new impulse to this pauperising  policy. Pitt and the country gentlemen wanted

strong armies to  fight  the French, and reversed the old policy as regards checks  upon  population. Hitherto

they had exercised control over the  numbers of  the labourers by refusing to build cottages; in 1771,  'an open

war  against cottages' had been carried on, and landlords  often pulled down  cottages, says Arthur Young, 'that

they may  never become the nests, as  they are called, of beggar brats.' But  now by giving extra allowance  to

large families, they put a  premium on early marriages, and  labourers were paid according to  the number of

their children. Further  extension of the allowance  system came from actual panic at home.  Farmers and

landowners  were intimidated by the labourers: the  landowners had themselves  according to Malthus at once

inflamed the  minds of their  labourers and preached to them submission. Rickburning  was  frequent; at

Swallowfield, in Wiltshire, the justices, 'under the  influence of the panic struck by the fires, so far yielded to

the  importunity of the farmers as to adopt the allowancesystem  during  the winter months.' In 1795 some

Berkshire justices 'and  other  discreet persons' issued a proclamation, which came to be  considered  as a guide

to all the magistrates of the South of  England. They  declared it to be their unanimous opinion that the  state of

the poor  required further assistance than had been  generally given them; and  with this view they held it

inexpedient  to regulate wages according to  the statutes of Elizabeth and  James; they would earnestly

recommend  farmers and others to  increase the pay of their labourers in  proportion to the present  price of

provisions; but if the farmers  refused, they would make  an allowance to every poor family in  proportion to its


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

IX. The Growth of Pauperism 35



Top




Page No 38


numbers.  They stated what they thought necessary for  a man and his wife  and children, which was to be

produced 'either by  his own and his  family's labour on an allowance from the poorrates.'  These were  the

beginnings of the allowance system, which under its  many  forms ended in thoroughly demoralising the

people; it had not  been long in operation before we hear the labourers described as  lazy, mutinous, and

imperious to the overseers. When grants in  aid of  wages were deemed insufficient, the men would go to a

magistrate to  complain, the magistrate would appeal to the  humanity of the overseer,  the men would add

threats, and the  overseer would give in. In the  parish of Bancliffe ' a man was  employed to look after the

paupers,  but they threatened to drown  him, and he was obliged to withdraw.' The  whole character of the

people was lowered by the admission that they  had a right to  relief independent of work. 

X. Malthus and the Law of Population

It was during this state of things, with population rapidly  increasing, that Malthus wrote. Yet he was not

thinking directly  of  the Poor Law, but of Godwin, who, under the influence of  Rousseau, had  in his Inquirer

ascribed all human ills to human  government and  institutions, and drawn bright pictures of what  might be in a

reformed  society. Malthus denied their possibility.  Under no system, he  contended, could such happiness be

insured;  human misery was not the  result of human injustice and of bad  institutions, but of an  inexorable law

of nature, viz., that  population tends to outstrip the  means of subsistence. This law  would in a few generations

counteract  the effects of the best  institutions that human wisdom could conceive.  It is remarkable  that though

in his first edition he gave a conclusive  answer to  Godwin, Malthus afterwards made an admission which

deducted  a  good deal from the force of his argument. To the 'positive check'  of misery and vice, he added the

'preventive check' of moral  restraint, namely, abstinence from marriage. To this Godwin made  the  obvious

reply that such a qualification virtually conceded  the  perfectibility of society. But Malthus still thought his

argument  conclusive as against Godwin's Communism. If private  property was  abolished, he said, all

inducements to moral  restraint would be taken  away. His prophecy has, however, since  his time, been refuted

by the  experience of the communistic  societies in America, which proves that  the absence of private  property

is not incompatible with moral  restraint. 

Is Malthus's law really true? We see that it rests on two  premisses. The first is, that the potential rate of

increase of  the  human race is such that population, if unchecked, would  double itself  in twentyfive years;

and Malthus assumes that this  rate is constant  in every race and at all times. His second  premiss is the law of

diminishing returns, i.e. that after a  certain stage of cultivation a  given piece of land will, despite  any

agricultural improvements, yield  a less proportionate return  to human labour; and this law is true.  Malthus did

not deny that  food might, for a time, increase faster than  population; but land  could not be increased, and if

the area which  supplied a people  were restricted, the total quantity of food which it  produced per  head must

be at length diminished, though this result  might be  long deferred. Malthus himself regarded both his

conclusions  as  equally selfevident. 'The first of these propositions,' he says,  'i considered as proved the

moment the American increase was  related;  and the second proposition as soon as it was  enunciated.' Why

then did  he write so long a book? 'The chief  object of my work,' he goes on to  say, 'was to inquire what

effects these laws, which I considered as  established in the  first six pages, had produced, and were likely to

produce, on  society;  a subject not very readily exhausted.' The  greater  part of his essay is an historical

examination of the growth  of  population and the checks on it which have obtained in different  ages and

countries; and he applies his conclusion to the  administration of the Poor Laws in England. 

Now there are grave doubts as to the universal truth of his  first  premiss. Some of his earlier opponents, as

Doubleday, laid  down the  proposition that fecundity varies inversely to  nutriment. Thus baldly  stated their

assertion is not true; but it  is au observed fact, as  Adam Smith noticed long ago, that the  luxurious classes

have few  children, while a 'halfstarved  Highland woman' may have a family of  twenty. Mr Herbert Spencer

again has asserted that fecundity varies  inversely to nervous  organisation, and this statement has been

accepted by Carey and  Bagehot. But it is not so much the increase of  brain power as the  worry and


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

X. Malthus and the Law of Population 36



Top




Page No 39


exhaustion of modern life which tends to  bring about  this result. Some statistics quoted by Mr Amasa Walker

tend to  prove this. He has shown that in Massachusetts, while there  are  about 980,000 persons of native birth

as against only 260,000  immigrants, the number of births in the two classes is almost  exactly  the same, the

number of marriages double as many in the  latter, as in  the former, and longevity less and mortality  greater

among the  Americans. Mr CliffeLeslie attributes this  fact to a decline in  fecundity on the part of American

citizens.  The whole question,  however, is veiled in great obscurity, and is  rather for physiologists  and

biologists to decide; but there do  seem to be causes at work which  preclude us from assuming with  Malthus

that the rate of increase is  invariable. 

Another American writer, Mr Henry George, has recently argued  that  Malthus was wrong and Godwin right,

that poverty is due to  human  injustice, to an unequal distribution of wealth, the result  of private  property in

land, and not to Malthus's law of the  increase of  population or to the law of diminishing returns, both  of

which he  altogether rejects. With regard to the latter he  urges with truth that  in certain communities, for

instance  California, where the law of  diminishing returns evidently does  not come into operation, the same

phenomenon of pauperism  appears. Now against Mr George it can be  proved by facts that  there are cases

where his contention is not true.  It is  noticeable that he makes no reference to France, Norway, and

Switzerlandall countries of peasant proprietors, and where  consequently the land is not monopolised by a

few. But it is  certain  that in all these countries, at any rate in the present  state of  agricultural knowledge and

skill, the law of diminishing  returns does  obtain; and it is useless to argue that in these  cases it is the  injustice

of man, and not the niggardliness of  nature, that is the  cause of poverty, and necessitates baneful  checks on

population. Still  I admit that Mr George's argument is  partially truea large portion of  pauperism and misery

is really  attributable to bad government and  injustice; but this does not  touch the main issue, or disprove the

law  of diminishing returns. 

To return to Malthus's first proposition. The phrase that  'population tends to outstrip the means of subsistence'

is vague  and  ambiguous. It may mean that population, if unchecked, would  outstrip  the means of subsistence;

or it may mean that population  does increase  faster than the means of subsistence. It is quite  clear that, in its

second sense, it is not true of England at the  present day. The  average quantity of food consumed per head is

yearly greater; and  capital increases more than twice as fast as  population. But the  earlier writers on

population invariably use  the phrase in the latter  sense, and apply it to the England of  their time. At the

present day  it can only be true in this latter  sense of a very few countries. It  has been said to be true in the

case of India, but even there the  assertion can only apply to  certain districts. Mr George, however, is  not

content to refute  Malthus's proposition in this sense; he denies  it altogether,  denies the statement in the sense

that population, if  unchecked,  would outstrip the means of subsistence, and lays down as a  general law that

there need be no fear of overpopulation if  wealth  were justly distributed. The experience of countries like

Norway and  Switzerland, however, where overpopulation does  exist, although the  distribution of wealth is

tolerably even,  shows that this doctrine is  not universally true. Another  criticism of Mr George's, however, is

certainly good, as far as  it goes. Malthus's proposition was supposed  to be strengthened by  Darwin's theory,

and Darwin himself says that it  was the study of  Malthus's book which suggested it to him; but Mr  George

rightly  objects to the analogy between man and animals and  plants. It is  true that animals, in their struggle for

existence, have  a  strictly limited amount of subsistence, but man can, by his  ingenuity and energy,

enormously increase his supply. The  objection  is valid, though it can hardly be said to touch the  main issue. 

I have spoken of the rapid growth of population in the period  we  are studying. We have to consider how

Malthus accounted for  it, and  how far his explanation is satisfactory, as well as what  practical  conclusions he

came to. In the rural districts he  thought the  excessive increase was the consequence of the bad  administration

of  the Poor Laws, and of the premium which they  put on early marriages.  This was true, but not the whole

truth;  there are other points to be  taken into account. In the old days  the younger labourers boarded in  the

farmhouses, and were of  course single men; no man could marry till  there was a cottage  vacant, and it was

the policy of the landlords in  the 'close  villages' to destroy cottages, in order to lessen the  rates. But  now the

farmers had risen in social position and refused to  board  the labourers in their houses. The ejected labourers,


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

X. Malthus and the Law of Population 37



Top




Page No 40


encouraged  by the allowance system, married recklessly, and though some  emigrated into the towns, a great

evil arose. The rural  population  kept increasing while the cottage accommodation as  steadily  diminished, and

terrible overcrowding was the result.  Owing to the  recklessness and demoralisation of the labourer the  lack of

cottages  no longer operated as any check on population.  The change in the  social habits of the farmers had

thus a  considerable effect on the  increase of rural population and  tended to aggravate the effects of  the

allowance system. 

In the towns the greatest stimulus came from the extension of  trade due to the introduction of machinery. The

artisan's horizon  became indistinct; there was no visible limit to subsistence. In  a  country like Norway, with a

stationary society built up of  small local  units, the labourer knows exactly what openings for  employment

there  are in his community; and it is well known that  the Norwegian peasant  hesitates about marriage till he is

sure of  a position which will  enable him to support a family. But in a  great town, among 'the  unavoidable

variations of manufacturing  labour,' all these definite  limits were removed. The artisan  could always hope

that the growth of  industry would afford  employment for any number of childrenan  expectation which the

enormously rapid growth of the woollen and  cotton manufactures  justified to a large extent. And the great

demand  for children's  labour in towns increased a man's income in proportion  to the  number of his family,

just as the allowance system did in the  country. 

What remedies did Malthus propose? The first was the  abolition of  the Poor Law. and he was not singular in

this  opinion. Many eminent  writers of the time believed it to be  intrinsically bad. He suggested  that at a given

date it should be  announced that no child born after  the lapse of a year should be  entitled to relief; the

improvident were  to be left to 'the  punishment of nature' and 'the uncertain support of  private  charity.' Others

saw that such treatment would be too hard;  that  a Poor Law of some sort was necessary, and that the problem

was  how to secure to the respectable poor the means of support  without  demoralising them. His second

remedy was moral  restraintabstention  from marriage till a man had means to  support a family, accompanied

by  perfectly moral conduct during  the period of celibacy. 

Let us now see what have been the actual remedies. The chief  is  the reform of the Poor Laws in 1834,

perhaps the most  beneficent Act  of Parliament which has been passed since the  Reform Bill. Its  principles

were (a) the application of the  workhouse test and the  gradual abolition of outdoor relief to  ablebodied

labourers; (b) the  formation of unions of parishes to  promote economy and efficiency,  these unions to be

governed by  Boards of Guardians elected by the  ratepayers, thus putting an  end to the mischievous reign of

the  Justices of the Peace; (c) a  central Board of Poor Law Commissioners,  with very large powers  to deal

with the Boards of Guardians and  control their action;  (d) a new bastardy law; (e) a mitigation of the  laws of

settlement. The effect of the new law was very remarkable. As  an  example, take the case of Sussex. Before

1834 there were in that  county over 6000 ablebodied paupers; two years later there were  124.  A similar

change took place in almost all the rural  districts, and the  riots and rickburning which had been so rife  began

to grow less  frequent. Equally remarkable was the effect  upon the rates. In 1818  they were nearly £8,000,000

in England  and Wales; in 1837 they had  sunk to a little over £4,000,000, and  are now only £7,500,000 in

spite  of the enormous growth of  population. The number of paupers, which in  1849 was 930,000, has

dwindled in 1881 to 800,000, though the  population has meanwhile  increased by more than 8,000,000.

Notwithstanding this  improvement the Poor Laws are by no means  perfect, and great  reforms are still needed. 

Next in importance as an actual remedy we must place  emigration.  Malthus despised it. He thought that 'from

the  natural unwillingness  of people to desert their native country,  and the difficulty of  clearing and cultivating

fresh soil, it  never is or can, that, even if  effectual for the time, the be  adequately adopted'; relief it afforded

would only be temporary,  'and the disorders would return with  increased virulence.' He  could not of course

foresee the enormous  development which would  be given to it by steam navigation, and the  close connection

established thereby between England and America.  Since 1815 eight  and a quarter millions of people have

emigrated from  the United  Kingdom; since 1847 three and a half millions have gone  from  England and Wales

alone; and this large emigration has of course  materially lightened the labour market. Nor could Malthus any


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

X. Malthus and the Law of Population 38



Top




Page No 41


more  foresee the great importation of food which would take place  in later  times. In his day England was

insulated by war and the  corn laws; now,  we import onehalf of our food, and pay for it  with our

manufactures. 

As to moral restraint, it is very doubtful, whether it has  been  largely operative. According to Professor

Jevons, writing  fifteen  years ago, it has been so only to a very small extent. Up  to 1860 the  number of

marriages was rather on the increase; but  if among the  masses, owing to cheap food, marriages have become

more frequent,  restraint has on the other hand certainly grown  among the middle  classes and the best of the

artisan class. 

I wish to speak of one more remedy, which Malthus himself  repudiated, namely, that of artificial checks on

the number of  children. It has been said that such questions should only be  discussed 'under the decent veil of

a dead language.' Reticence  on  them is necessary to wholesomeness of mind; but we ought  nevertheless  to

face the problem, for it is a vital one. These  preventive checks on  births excite our strong moral repugnance.

Men may call such  repugnance prejudice, but it is perfectly  logical, because it is a  protest against the

gratification of a  strong instinct while the  duties attaching to it are avoided.  Still our moral repugnance should

not prevent our considering the  question. Let us examine results. What  evidence is there as to  the effects of a

system of artificial checks?  We know that at  least one European nation, the French, has to some  extent

adopted  them. Now we find that in the purely rural Department  of the  Eure, where the population, owing

presumably to the widespread  adoption of artificial checks, is on the decline, although the  district is the best

cultivated in France and enjoys considerable  material prosperity, the general happiness promised is not found.

This Department comes first in statistics of crime; onethird of  these crimes are indecent outrages; another

third are paltry  thefts;  and infanticide also is rife. Though this is very  incomplete evidence,  it shows at least

that you may adopt these  measures without obtaining  the promised results. The idea that a  stationary and

materially  prosperous population will necessarily  be free from vice is  unreasonable enough in itself, and there

is  the evidence of experience  against it. Indeed, one strong  objection to any such system is to be  found in the

fact that a  stationary population is not a healthy  condition of things in  regard to national life; it means the

removal  of a great stimulus  to progress. One incentive to invention, in  particular, is  removed in France by

attempts to adapt population to  the existing  means of subsistence; for in this respect it is certainly  true  that the

struggle for existence is essential to progress. Such  practices, moreover, prove injurious to the children

themselves.  The  French peasant toils ceaselessly to leave each of his  children a  comfortable maintenance. It

would be better for them  to be brought up  decently, and then left to struggle for their  own maintenance. Much

of  the genius and inventive power in  English towns has come from the  rural districts with men  belonging to

large families, who started in  life impressed with  the idea that they must win their own way. It is  wrong to

consider this question from the point of view of wealth  alone; we  cannot overrate the importance of family

life as the source  of  all that is best in national life. Often the necessity of  supporting and educating a large

family is a training and  refining  influence in the lives of the parents, and the one thing  that makes  the

ordinary man conscious of his duties, and turns  him into a good  citizen. In the last resort we may say that

such  practices are  unnecessary in England at the present day. A man in  the superior  artisan or middle classes

has only to consider when  he will have  sufficient means to rear an average number of  children; that is, he

need only regulate the time of his  marriage. Postponement of marriage,  and the willing emigration of  some of

his children when grown up,  does, in his case, meet the  difficulty. He need not consider whether  there is room

in the  world for more, for there is room; and, in the  interests of  civilisation, it is not desirable that a nation

with a  great  history and great qualities should not advance in numbers. For  the labouring masses, on the other

hand, with whom prudential  motives  have no weight, the only true remedy is to carry out such  great  measures

of social reform as the improvement of their  dwellings,  better education and better amusements, and thus lift

them into the  position now held by the artisan, where moral  restraints are  operative. Above all, it must be

remembered that  this is not a purely  economic problem, nor is it to be solved by  mechanical contrivances.  To

reach the true solution we must  tenaciously hold to a high ideal of  spiritual life. What the  mechanical

contrivances might perchance give  us is not what we  desire for our country. The true remedies, on the  other

hand,  imply a growth towards that purer and higher condition of  society  for which alone we care to strive. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

X. Malthus and the Law of Population 39



Top




Page No 42


XI. The WageFund Theory

Besides originating the theory of population which bears his  name,  Malthus was the founder of that doctrine

of wages which,  under the  name of the wagefund theory, was accepted for fifty  years in England.  To

ascertain what the theory is we may take  Mill's statement of it, as  given in his review of Thornton On  Labour

in 1869. 'There is supposed  to be,' he says, 'at any given  instant, a sum of wealth which is  unconditionally

devoted to the  payment of wages of labour. This sum is  not regarded as  unalterable, for it is augmented by

saving, and  increases with  the progress of wealth; but it is reasoned upon as at  any given  moment a

predetermined amount. More than that amount it is  assumed that the wagesreceiving class cannot possibly

divide  among  them; that amount, and no less, they cannot possibly fail  to obtain.  So that the sum to be

divided being fixed, the wages  of each depend  solely on the divisor, the number of  participants.' This theory

was  implicitly believed from Malthus's  time to about 1870; we see it  accepted, for instance, in Miss

Martineau's Tales. And from the theory  several conclusions were  deduced which, owing to their practical

importance, it is well to  put in the forefront of our inquiry as to  its truth. It is these  conclusions which have

made the theory itself  and the science to  which it belongs an offence to the whole working  class. It was  said

in the first place that according to the wagefund  theory,  TradesUnions could not at any given time effect a

general  rise  in wages. It was, indeed, sometimes admitted that in a particular  trade the workmen could obtain

a rise by combination, but this  could  only be, it was alleged, at the expense of workmen in other  trades.  If, for

instance, the men in the building trade got  higher wages  through their Union, those in the iron foundries or  in

some other  industry must suffer to an equivalent extent. In  the next place it was  argued that combinations of

workmen could  not in the longrun increase  the fund out of which wages were  paid. Capital might be

increased by  saving, and, if this saving  Was more rapid than the increase in the  number of labourers,  wages

would rise, but it was denied that Unions  could have any  effect in forcing such an increase of saving. And

hence  it  followed that the only real remedy for low wages was a limitation  of the number of the labourers.

The rate of wages, it was said,  depended entirely on the efficacy of checks to population. 

The error lay in the premisses. The old economists, it may be  observed, very seldom examined their

premisses. For this theory  assumes  (1) that either the capital of a particular individual  available for the

payment of wages is fixed, or, at any rate, the  total capital of the community so available is fixed; and (2)  that

wages are always paid out of capital. Now it is plainly not  true that  a particular employer makes up his mind

to spend a  fixed quantity of  money on labour; the amount spent varies with a  number of  circumstances

affecting the prospect of profit on the  part of the  capitalist, such, for instance, as the price of  labour. Take the

instance of a strike of agricultural labourers  in Ireland, given by Mr  Trench to Nassau Senior. He was

employing  one hundred men at 10d. a  day, thus spending on wages £25 a week.  The men struck for higher

pay   a minimum of 1s. 2d., and the  more capable men to have more. Trench  offered to give the wages  asked

for, but greatly reduced his total  expenditure, as it would  not pay to employ so many men at the higher  rate.

Thus only  seventeen were employed; the other eightythree  objected, and it  ended in all going back to work

at the old rate. The  fact is,  that no individual has a fixed wagefund, which it is not in  his  power either to

diminish or increase. Just as he may reduce the  total amount which he spends on labour, rather than pay a rate

of  wages which seems incompatible with an adequate profit, so he may  increase that total amount, in order to

augment the wages of his  labourers, by diminishing the sum he spends upon himself or by  employing capital

which is lying idle, if he thinks that even  with  the higher rate of wages he can secure a sufficiently

remunerative  return upon his investment. Thus the workman may,  according to  circumstances, get higher or

lower wages than the  current rate,  without any alteration in the quantity of  employment given. When wages

in Dorset and Wilts were 7s., the  labourers, if they had had  sufficient intelligence and power of  combination,

might have forced  the farmers to pay them 8s. or  9s., for the latter were making very  high profits. As a matter

of  fact, where the workmen have been strong,  and the profits made by  the employers large, the former have

often  forced the employers  to give higher wages. 

Neither is it true that there is in the hands of the  community as  a whole, at any given time, a fixed quantity of


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XI. The WageFund Theory 40



Top




Page No 43


capital for supplying  the wants of the labourers, so much food,  boots, hats, clothes, etc.,  which neither

employers nor workmen  can increase. It used to be said  that a rise in money wages would  simply mean that

the price of all the  commodities purchased by  the labourers would rise proportionately,  owing to the increase

of demand, and that their real wages, i.e. the  number of things  they could purchase with their money, would

be no  greater than  before. But, as a matter of fact, the supply can be  increased as  fast as the demand. It is true

that between two harvests  the  available quantity of corn is fixed, but that of most other  commodities can be

increased at a short notice. For commodities  are  not stored up for consumption in great masses, but are being

continually produced as the demand for them arises. 

So far I have been speaking of the theory as applied to wages  at a  particular time. Now, what did it further

imply of wages in  the  longrun? According to Ricardo's law, which has been adopted  by  Lassalle and the

Socialists, wages depend on the ratio between  population and capital. Capital may be gradually increased by

saving,  and population may be gradually diminished; but Ricardo  thought that  the condition of the labourer

was surely on the  decline, because  population was advancing faster than capital.  While admitting

occasionally that there had been changes in the  standard of comfort,  he yet disregarded these in his general

theory, and assumed that the  standard was fixed; that an increase  of wages would lead to an  increase of

population, and that wages  would thus fall again to their  old rate, or even lower. The  amount of corn

consumed by the labourer  would not diminish, but  that of all other commodities would decline.  Later

economists  have qualified this statement of the supposed law.  Mill showed  that the standard of comfort was

not fixed, but might vary  indefinitely. This being the case, the labourer might sink even  lower  than Ricardo

supposed possible, for population might  increase till the  labourer had not only less of everything else,  but was

forced down to  a lower staple of life than corn, for  instance, potatoes. And this  has, as a matter of fact, taken

place in some countries. But, on the  other hand, the standard  might rise, as it has risen in England; and  Mill

thought that it  would rise yet more. At first this was his only  hope for the  working classes. At a later period

he trusted that the  labourer,  by means of cooperation, might become more and more  selfemploying, and so

obtain both profits and wages. 

It is interesting to inquire how this wagefund theory grew  up.  Why was it held that employers could not give

higher real  wages? Its  origin is easy to understand. When Malthus wrote his  essay on  population, there had

been a series of bad harvests, and  in those days  but small supplies of corn could be obtained from  abroad.

Thus year  after year there seemed to be a fixed quantity  of food in the country  and increasing numbers

requiring food.  Population was growing faster  than subsistence, and increased  money wages could not

increase the  quantity of food that was to  be had. Thus in 1800, when corn was l27s.  the quarter, it was  clear

that the rich could not help the poor by  giving them higher  wages, for this would simply have raised the price

of the fixed  quantity of corn. Malthus assumed that the amount of food  was  practically fixed; therefore,

unless population diminished, as  years went on, wages would fall, because worse soils would be  cultivated

and there would be increased difficulty in obtaining  food.  But the period he had before his eyes was quite

exceptional; after the  peace, good harvests came and plenty of  corn; food grew cheaper,  though population

advanced at the same  rate. So that the theory in  this shape was true only of the  twenty years from 1795 to

1815. But,  when it had once been said  that wages depended on the proportion  between population and  food, it

was easy to substitute capital for  food and say that  they depended on the proportion between population  and

capital,  food and capital being wrongly identified. Then when the  identification was forgotten, it was

supposed that there is at  any  given moment a fixed quantity of wagecapitalfood, boots,  hats,  furniture,

clothes, etc.  destined for the payment of  wages, which  neither employers nor workmen can diminish or

increase, and thus the  rate of wages came to be regarded as  regulated by a natural law,  independent of the will

of either  party. 

We have already seen that this theory is false; we have now  to  substitute for it some truer theory, and explain

thereby the  actual  phenomena of the labour market, such, for instance, as the  fact that  wages at Chicago or

New York are twice as high as they  are in England,  while the prices of the necessaries of life are  lower.

Though modern  economists have pointed out the fallacies of  the old wagefund theory,  no economist has yet


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XI. The WageFund Theory 41



Top




Page No 44


succeeded in  giving us a complete theory of wages  in its place. I believe  indeed that so complicated a set of

conditions  as are involved  cannot be explained by any one formula, and that the  attempt to  do so leads to

fallacies. Yet I am also aware that the  public  seem to feel themselves aggrieved that economists will not now

provide them with another convenient set phrase in place of the  wagefund theory, and are inclined to doubt

the validity of their  explanations in consequence. Now, wages in a given country depend  on  two things: the

total amount of produce in the country, and  the manner  in which that produce is divided. To work out the

former problem we  must investigate all the causes which affect  the whole amount of  wealth produced, the

natural resources of the  country, its political  institutions, the skill, intelligence, and  inventive genius of its

inhabitants. The division of the produce,  on the other hand, is  determined mainly by the proportion between

the number of labourers  seeking employment and the quantity of  capital seeking investment; or,  to put the

case in a somewhat  different way, instead of saying that  wages are paid out of  storedup capital, we now say

that they are the  labourer's share  of the produce. What the labourer's share will be  depends first  on the

quantity of produce he can turn out, and  secondly, on the  nature of the bargain which he is able to make with

his employer.  We are now in a position to explain the question put  above, why  wages in America are double

what they are in England. An  American  ironmaster, if asked to give a reason for the high wages he  pays,

would say that the land determines the rate of wages in America,  because under the Free Homestead Law,

any man can get a piece of  land  for a nominal sum, and no puddler will work for less than he  can get  by

working on this land. Now, in the Western States the  soil is very  fertile, and though the average yield is lower

than  in Wiltshire, the  return in proportion to the labour expended is  greater. Moreover,  labour being scarce,

the workman has to be  humoured; he is in a  favourable position in making his bargain  with the employer, and

obtains a large share of the produce. Thus  agricultural wages are very  high, and this explains also the  cause of

high wages in the American  irontrade and other American  industries. In consequence of these high  wages

the manufacturer  is obliged to make large use of machinery, and  much of our  English machinery, e.g. that of

the Leicester boot and  shoe  trade, has been invented in America. Now, better machinery makes  labour more

efficient and the produce per head of the labourers  greater. Further, according to the testimony of capitalists,

the  workmen work harder in America than in England, because they work  with hope; they have before them

the prospect of rising in the  world  by their accumulations. Thus it is that the produce of  American

manufactures is great, and allows of the labourer  obtaining a large  share. High wages in America are

therefore  explained by the quantity  of produce the labourer turns out being  great and by the action of

competition being in his favour. 

There are, however, other causes influencing the rate of  wages in  America which are less favourable to the

workmen.  Protection, for  instance, diminishes real wages by enhancing the  cost of many articles  in common

use, such as cutlery. It is owing  to Protection also that  capitalists are able to obtain  exceptionally high profits

at the  expense of the workmen. By  combining and forming rings they can govern  the market, and not  only

control prices but dictate the rate of wages.  Six or seven  years ago, the whole output of Pennsylvanian

anthracite  was in  the hands of a few companies. Hence it was that, in the Labour  War of 1877, the workmen

declared that, while they did not mind  wages  being fixed by competition, they would not endure their  being

fixed by  rings, and that such rings would produce a  revolution. And the  monopoly of these companies was

only broken  through by a great  migration of workmen to the West. The  experience of America in this

instance is of interest in showing  how, as industry advances, trade  tends to get concentrated into  fewer hands;

hence the danger of  monopolies. It has even been  asserted that Free Trade must lead to  great natural

monopolies.  This may be true of a country like America  which has internal but  not external free trade, but

only of such a  country; for foreign  competition would prevent a knot of capitalists  from ever  obtaining full

control of the market. 

I have shown why wages are higher in America than in England.  We  may go on to inquire why they are

higher in England than in  any other  part of Europe. The great reason is that the total  amount of wealth

produced in this country is larger, and that  from a variety of causes,  material and moral. The chief material

causes are our unrivalled  stores of coal and iron, and perhaps,  above all, our geographical  position. On the

moral side, our  political institutions, being  favourable to liberty, have  developed individual energy and


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XI. The WageFund Theory 42



Top




Page No 45


industry  in a degree unknown in  any other country. On the other hand, it has  been said that the  exclusion of

the labourer from the land in England  must have  tended to lower wages. And no doubt the adoption of a

system  of  large farms has driven the labourers into the towns, and made the  competition for employment

there very keen. But, to set against  this,  the efficiency of English manufacturing labour is largely  due to this

very fact, that it is not able to shift on to the  land. While in  America the whole staff of a cotton factory may

be  changed in three  years, in England the artisan 'sticks to his  trade,' and brings up his  children to it; and thus

castes are  formed with inherited aptitudes,  which render labour more  efficient, and its produce greater. I

believe  the higher wages  obtained in England, in comparison with the  Continent, are mainly  due to greater

efficiency of labour  that this  is the chief  cause why the total produce is greater. But if we go  further, and

ask what determines the division of the produce, the  answer must  be: mainly competition. To return to the

comparison with  America,  the reason why the English labourer gets lower wages than the  American is the

great competition for employment in the  overstocked  labourmarket of this country. 

I must notice an objection to the theory of wages as stated  above.  Wages, I have explained, are the labourers'

share of the  produce, and  are paid out of it. But, it may be said, while our  new Law Courts, or  an ironclad, are

being built  operations  which take a long time  before there is any completed result  how  can it be correctly

held  that the labourer is paid out of the  produce? It is of course  perfectly true that he is maintained  during

such labours only by the  produce of others; and that  unless some great capitalist had either  accumulated

capital, or  borrowed it, the labourer could not be paid.  But this has nothing  to do with the rate of wages. That

is determined  by the amount of  the produce and is independent of the method of  payment. What the  capitalist

does is merely to pay in advance the  labourer's share,  as a matter of convenience. 

We will next inquire what are the limits to a rise of wages  in any  particular trade? The answer depends on

two thing. First,  is the  capitalist getting more than the ordinary rate of profits?  If he is  not, he will resist a rise

on the ground that he 'cannot  afford' to  pay more wages. This is what an arbitrator, for  instance, might say if

he examined the books, and he would mean  by it that, if the employer  had to raise his wages, he would have

to be content with lower profits  than he could make in other  trades. As a matter of fact, however,  capitalists

often do make  exceptionally high profits, and it is in  such cases that  TradesUnions have been very

successful in forcing  them to share  these exceptional profits with their men. Secondly,  though the  employer

be getting only ordinary profits, his workmen may  still  be strong enough to force him to give higher wages,

but he will  only do so permanently if he can compensate himself by raising  the  price of his commodity. Thus

the second limit to a rise in  wages in a  particular trade is the amount which the consumer can  be forced to pay

for its products. Workmen have often made  mistakes by not taking this  into account, and have checked the

demand for the articles which they  produced, and so brought about  a loss both to their masters and

themselves. In a particular  trade then the limit to a rise in wages is  reached when any  further rise will drive

the employer out of the  trade, or when  the increased price of the commodity will check the  demand. When

dealing with the general trade of a country, however, we  can  neglect prices altogether, since there can be no

such thing as a  general rise in prices while the value of the precious metal is  stationary. Could, then, the

whole body of the workmen throughout  the  kingdom, by good organisation, compel employers to accept

lower  profits? If there was a general strike, would it be the  interest of  the employers to give way? It is

impossible to answer  such a question  beforehand. It would be a sheer trial of strength  between the two

parties, the outcome of which cannot be  predicted, for nothing of the  kind has ever actually taken place.  And

though there is now a nearer  approximation than ever before  to the supposed conditions, there has  as yet been

nothing like a  general organisation of workmen. 

Assuming, however, that the workmen succeeded in such a  strike, we  can then ask what would be the effect

of a general  rise of wages in  the longrun? One of several results might  ensue. The remuneration of

employers having declined, their  numbers might diminish, and the  demand for labour would then  diminish

also and wages fall. Or again  the decline in the rate of  interest might check the accumulation of  capital, thus

again  diminishing the demand for labour. Or, on the  other hand, the  rise in wages might be permanent, the

remuneration of  employers  still proving sufficient, and the accumulation of capital  remaining unchecked. Or


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XI. The WageFund Theory 43



Top




Page No 46


lastly, higher wages might lead to  greater  efficiency of labour, and in this case profits would not  fall. It is

impossible to decide on a priori grounds which of  these results would  actually take place. 

Returning to our period, we may apply these principles to  explain  the fall in wages between 1790 and 1820.

During this  period, while  rent was doubled, interest also was nearly doubled  (this by the way  disproves Mr

George's theory on that point), and  yet wages fell. We  may take Mr Porter's estimate. 'In some few  cases

there had been an  advance of wages, but this occurred only  to skilled artisans, and even  with them the rise

was wholly  incommensurate with the increased cost  of all the necessaries of  life. The mere labourer... did not

participate in this partial  compensation for high prices, but was...  at the same or nearly  the same wages as had

been given before the  war.' In 1790 the  weekly wage skilled artisans and farm labourers  respectively  would

buy 82 and 169 pints of corn: in 1800 they would  buy 53 and  83. According to Mr Barton, a contemporary

writer, wages  between  1760 and 1820, 'estimated in money, had risen 100 per cent.;  estimated in

commodities, they had fallen 33 per cent.' What were  the  causes of this fall? Let us first take the case of the

artisans and  manufacturing labourers. One cause in their case was  a series of bad  harvests. To explain how

this wOUld affect wages  in manufactures we  must fall back on the deductive method, and  assume certain

conditions  from which to draw our conclusions. Let  us suppose two villages side  by side, one agricultural, the

other  manufacturing, in the former of  which the land is owned by  landowners, and tilled by labour employed

by farmers. Suppose the  manufacturing village to be fed by its  neighbours in exchange for  cutlery. Then, if

there is a bad harvest in  the agricultural  village, every labourer in the manufacturing village  will have to

spend more on corn. The owners of land will gain  enormously; the  farmers will be enriched in so far as they

can retain  the  increased prices for themselves, which they will do, if holding  on leases. But every one else

will be poorer, for there has been  a  loss of wealth. In order to get his corn, the labourer will  have to  give more

of his share of the produce; and hence the  demand for all  other goods, which are produced for the labourers'

consumption, will  diminish. Nothing affects the labourer so much  as good or bad  harvests, and it is because

of its tendency to  neutralise the  consequences of deficient crops at home, that the  labourer has gained  so

much by Free Trade. When we have a bad  harvest here, we get plenty  of corn from America, and the  labourer

pays nearly the same price for  his loaf, and has as much  money as before left to spend on other  commodities.

Still, even  at the present day, some depression of trade  is generally  associated with bad harvests. And though

Free Trade  lessens the  force of their incidence on a particular locality, it  widens the  area affected by thema

bad harvest in Brazil may prejudice  trade  in England. 

The next point to be taken into consideration is the huge  taxation  which fell upon the workmen at this time;

even as late  as 1834 half  the labourers' wages went in taxes. There was also  increase in the  National Debt.

During the war we had nominally  borrowed £600,000,000,  although owing to the way in which the  loans

were raised, the actual  sum which came into the national  exchequer was only £350,000,000. All  this capital

was withdrawn  from productive industry, and the demand  for labour was  diminished to that extent. Lastly,

the labourer was  often  actually paid in bad coin, quantities of which were bought by  the  manufacturers for the

purpose; and he was robbed by the truck  system, through which the employer became a retail trader, with

power  to overprice his goods to an indefinite extent. 

Some of these causes affected the agricultural and  manufacturing  labourers alike; they suffered, of course,

equally  from bad harvests.  But we have seen in former lectures that there  were agrarian and  social changes

during this period, which told  upon the agricultural  labourer exclusively. The enclosures took  away his

commonrights, and  where the land, before enclosure, had  been already in cultivation,  they diminished the

demand for his  labour, besides depriving him of  the hope of becoming himself a  farmer, and, to mention a

seemingly  small but really serious  loss, cutting off his supply of milk, which  had been provided by  the 'little

people' who kept cows on the commons.  He was further  affected by the enormous rise in cottage rents. Mr

Drummond, a  Surrey magistrate, told the Commission on Labourers' Wages  in  1824, that he remembered

cottages with good gardens letting for  30s. before the war, while at the time when he was speaking the  same

were fetching £5, £7, or £10. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XI. The WageFund Theory 44



Top




Page No 47


This rise was due to causes we have before had in review, to  the  growth of population, the expulsion of

servants from the  farmhouses,  and the demolition of cottages in close villages.  When the labourers,  to meet

the deficiency, built cottages for  themselves on the wastes,  the farmers pulled them down, and, if  the

labourers rebuilt them,  refused to employ them, with the  result that such labourers became  thieves and

poachers. Again,  during this period, it was not uncommon  for the farmers  absolutely to determine what wages

should be paid, and  the men in  their ignorance were entirely dependent on them. Here are  two  facts to prove

their subservience. In one instance, two pauper  families who had cost their parish no less than £20 a year

each,  were  given instead an acre of land rent free, and the rates were  relieved  to that amount; but though

successful, the experiment  was  discontinued, 'lest the labourer should become independent of  the  farmer.'

And this is the statement of an Essex farmer in  1793: 'I was  the more desirous to give them an increase of

pay,  as it was unasked  for by the men, who were content with less than  they had a right to  expect.' The

agricultural labourer at this  time was in an entirely  helpless condition in bargaining with his  employer. Nor

were the  farmers the only class who profited by his  deterioration; for the high  rents of the time were often

paid out  of the pocket of the labourer.  The period was one of costly wars,  bad seasons, and industrial  changes.

The misfortunes of the  labouring classes were partly  inevitable, but they were also  largely the result of human

injustice,  of the selfish and  grasping use made of a power which exceptional  circumstances had  placed in the

hands of landowners, farmers, and  capitalists. 

XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent

In Political Economy, as in other sciences, a careful study  of  method is an absolute necessity. And this

subject of method  will come  into special prominence in the present lecture, because  we have now to  consider

the writings of a man of extraordinary  intellect and force,  who, beyond any other thinker, has left the  impress

of his mind on  economic method. Yet even he would have  been saved from several  fallacies, if he had paid

more careful  attention to the necessary  limitations of the method which he  employed. It may be truly said that

David Ricardo has produced a  greater effect even than Adam Smith on  the actual practice of men  as well as

on the theoretical consideration  of social problems.  His book has been at once the great prop of the  middle

classes,  and their most terrible menace; the latter, because  from it have  directly sprung two great textbooks

of Socialism, Das  Kapital of  Karl Marx, and the Progress and Poverty of Mr Henry George.  And  yet for thirty

or forty years Ricardo's writings did more than  those of any other author to justify in the eyes of men the

existing  state of society. 

Ricardo's life has little in it of external interest. He made  his  fortune on the Stock Exchange by means of his

great financial  abilities, and then retired and devoted himself to literature.  During  the few years that he sat in

Parliament, he worked (we  have it on  Huskisson's testimony) a great change in the opinions  of legislators,

even in those of the country squiresa remarkable  fact, since his  speeches are highly abstract, and contain

few  allusions to current  politics, reading in fact like chapters from  his book. We may notice  one direct effect

of his speeches: they  were the most powerful  influence in determining the resumption of  cash payments. In

his  private life he associated much with  Bentham and James Mill. 

James Mill, like Bentham and Austin, was a staunch adherent  of the  deductive method, and it was partly

through Mill's  influence that  Ricardo adopted it. Mill was his greatest friend;  it was he who  persuaded him

both to go into Parliament, and to  publish his great  book. Ricardo's political opinions in fact  merely reflect

those of  James Mill, and the other philosophical  Radicals of the time, though  in Political Economy he was

their  teacher. Ricardo reigned without  dispute in English Economics  from 1817 to 1848, and though his

supremacy has since then been  often challenged, it is by no means  entirely overthrown. His  influence was

such that his method became the  accepted method of  economists; and to understand how great the  influence

of method  may be, you should turn from his writings and  those of his  followers to Adam Smith, or to Sir

Henry Maine, where you  come in  contact with another cast of mind, and will find yourselves in  a  completely

different mental atmosphere. Now what is this  deductive  method which Ricardo employed? It consists in


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent 45



Top




Page No 48


reasoning  from one or  two extremely simple propositions down to a series of  new laws. He  always employed

this method, taking as his great  postulate that all  men will on all matters follow their own  interests. The

defect of the  assumption lies in its too great  simplicity as a theory of human  nature. Men do not always know

their own interest. Bagehot points out  that the £10 householders,  who were enfranchised by the first Reform

Bill, were after 1832  the most heavily taxed class in the community,  though the remedy  was in their own

hands; because they were ignorant  and apathetic.  And even when men know their interests, they will not

always  follow them; other influences intervene, custom, prejudice,  even  fear. Cairnes frankly admits these

defects in Ricardo's method;  but it took economists some thirty or forty years to learn the  necessity of testing

their conclusions by facts and observations.  Since 1848 their attitude has improved; it is now seen that we

must  insist upon the verification of our premisses, and examine  our  deductions by the light of history. 

Ricardo has deduced from very simple data a famous law of  industrial progress. In an advancing community,

he says, rent  must  rise, profits fall, and wages remain about the same. We  shall find  from actual facts that this

law has been often true,  and is capable of  legitimate application, though Mr CliffeLeslie  would repudiate it

altogether; but it cannot be accepted as a  universal law. The  historical method, on the other hand, is  impotent

of itself to give us  a law of progress, because so many  of the facts on which it relies  are, in Economics,

concealed from  us. By the historical method we mean  the actual observation of  the course of economic

history, and the  deduction from it of laws  of economic progress; and this method, while  most useful in

checking the results of deduction is, by itself, full  of danger  from its tendency to set up imperfect

generalisations. Sir  H.  Maine and M. Laveleye, for instance, have taken an historical  survey of landtenure,

and drawn from it the conclusion that the  movement of property in land is always from collective to

individual  ownership; and Mr Ingram, again, alluding to this law,  accepts it as  true that there is a natural

tendency towards  private property in  land. He can build his argument on the  universal practice from Java to

the Shetlands, and it would seem  a legitimate conclusion that the  tendency will be constant. Yet  there is at the

present day a distinct  movement towards replacing  private by collective ownership, due to the  gradual change

in the  opinions of men as to the basis on which  property in land should  rest. Mill, in 1848, argued that where

the  cultivator was not  also the owner, there was no justification for  private ownership;  later in his life, he

advocated the confiscation of  the unearned  increment in land. If we ask, 'Was he right?' the answer  must be:

Every single institution of society is brought to the test of  utility and general national wellbeing; hence,

private property  in  land, if it fails under this test, will not continue. So too  with the  rate of interest: older

economists have insisted on the  necessity of a  certain rate, in order to encourage the  accumulation of capital;

but  we may fairly ask whether the rate  of remuneration for the use of  capital is not too highwhether we

could not obtain sufficient capital  on easier terms? These  considerations show that, in predicting the  actual

course of  industrial progress, we must not be content to say  that because  there has been a movement in a

certain direction in the  pastfor  example, one from status to contractit will therefore  continue  in the future.

We must always apply the test, Does it fit in  with  the urgent present requirements of human nature? 

Ricardo's influence on legislation, to which I have already  alluded, was twofold; it bore directly upon the

special subject  of  currency and finance; and, what is more remarkable, it  affected  legislation in general. As

regards finance, his  pamphlets are the real  justification of our monetary system, and  are still read by all who

would master the principles of  currency. With respect to other  legislation, he and his friends  have the great

credit of having helped  to remove not merely  restrictions on trade in general, but those in  particular which

bore hardest on the labourer. When Joseph Hume, in  1824, proposed  the repeal of the Combination Laws, he

said he had been  moved  thereto by Ricardo. But though Ricardo advocated the removal of  restrictions which

injured the labourer, he deprecated all  restrictions in his favour; he ridiculed the Truck Acts, and  supported

the opposition of the manufacturers to the Factory Acts    an opposition which, be it remembered, though

prompted by mere  class  interest, was also supported in the name and on the then  accepted  principles of

economic science. 

In this way Ricardo became the prop, as I have called him, of  the  middle classes. Throughout his treatise

there ran the idea of  natural  law, which seemed to carry with it a sort of  justification of the  existing


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent 46



Top




Page No 49


constitution of society as  inevitable. Hence his doctrines  have proved the readiest weapons  wherewith to

combat legislative  interference or any proposals to  modify existing institutions. Hence,  too, his actual

conclusions,  although gloomy and depressing, were  accepted without question by  most of his contemporaries.

Another  school, however, has grown  up, accepting his conclusions as true under  existing social  conditions,

but seeing through the fallacy of his  'natural law.'  These are the Socialists, through whom Ricardo has

become a  terror to the middle classes. The Socialists believe that, by  altering the social conditions which he

assumed to be  unalterable,  Ricardo's conclusions can be escaped. Karl Marx and  Lassalle have  adopted

Ricardo's law of wages; but they have  argued that, since by  this law wages, under our present social

institutions, can never be  more than sufficient for the bare  subsistence of the labourer, we are  bound to

reconsider the whole  foundation of society. Marx also simply  accepts Ricardo's theory  of value. The value of

products, said  Ricardo, is determined by  the quantity of the labour expended on them;  and Marx uses this

statement to deduce the theorem that the whole  value of the  produce rightly belongs to labour, and that by

having to  share  the produce with capital the labourer is robbed. 

Mr Henry George, again, the latest Socialist writer, is  purely and  entirely a disciple of Ricardo. The whole

aim of his  treatise,  Progress and Poverty, is to prove that rent must rise  as society  advances and wealth

increases. It is not the labourer,  Ricardo  reasoned, who will be the richer for this progress, nor  the  capitalist,

but the owner of land. Mr George's theory of  progress is  the same. Putting aside his attempt to show a

connection between the  laws of interest and wages, which he  contends will rise and fall  together, there is little

difference  between his conclusions and  Ricardo's. Others before Mr George  had clearly enough seen this

bearing of the law of rent. Roesler,  the German economist, says:  'Political Economy would only be a  theory

of human degradation and  impoverishment, if the law of  rent worked without modification.' 

Now let us see what are the assumptions on which Ricardo  grounded  his law about the course of rent, wages,

and profits in  a progressive  community. The pressure of population, he argued,  makes men resort to  inferior

soils; hence the cost of  agricultural produce increases, and  therefore rent rises. But why  will profits fall?

Because they depend  upon the cost of labour,  and the main element in determining this is  the cost of the

commodities consumed by the workmen. Ricardo assumes  that the  standard of comfort is fixed. If, therefore,

the cost of a  quartern loaf increases, and the labourer is to obtain the same  number of them, his wages must

rise, and profits therefore must  fall.  Lastly, why should wages remain stationary? Because,  assuming that the

labourer's standard of comfort is fixed, a rise  of wages or a fall in  prices will only lead to a proportionate

increase of population. The  history of the theory of rent is very  interesting, but it is out of  our road, so I can

only lightly  touch upon it. Adam Smith had no clear  or consistent theory at  all on the subject, and no distinct

views as  to the relation  between rent and price. The modern doctrine is first  found in a  pamphlet by a

practical farmer named James Anderson,  published in  1777, the year after the appearance of The Wealth of

Nations; but  it attracted little attention till it was simultaneously  restated by Sir Edward West, and by

Malthus in his pamphlet on  the  Corn Laws. Had the theory, however, been left in the shape in  which  they

stated it, it would have had little influence. It was  Ricardo,  who, pUzzled by the question of rent, snatched at

the  theory, and gave  it currency by embodying it in his whole  doctrine of value and of  economic

development. 

Ricardo's two great positive conclusions are: first, that the  main  cause of rent is the necessity of cultivating

inferior soil  as  civilisation advances; and secondly, that rent is not the  cause but  the result of price. The theory

has been disputed and  criticised, but  nearly all the objections have come from persons  who have not

understood it. We may say conclusively that, as a  theory of the causes  of rent, apart from that general

doctrine of  industrial development of  which in Ricardo it forms a part, the  theory is true. The one  formidable

objection which can be urged  against it is that the rise in  rents in modern times has been due  not so much to

the necessity of  resorting to inferior soils, as  to improvements in agriculture; but  when Professor Thorold

Rogers  attacks the theory on this ground, he  merely proves that Ricardo  has overlooked some important

causes which  have led to an  increase of rents since the Middle Ages. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent 47



Top




Page No 50


What, then, are we justified in stating to be the ultimate  causes  of rent? First, the fertility of the soil and the

skill of  the  cultivator, by which he is able to raise a larger produce  than is  necessary for his own subsistence;

this makes rent  physically  possible. Next, the fact that land is limited in  quantity and quality;  that is, that the

supply of the land most  desirable from its situation  and fertility is less than the  demand: this allows of rent

being  exacted. The early colonists in  America paid no rent, because there  was an abundance of land open  to

every one; but twenty years later,  rent was paid because  population had grown. Let us see exactly what

happens in such a  case. A town is founded on the seacoast; as it  grows, the people  in that town have to get

some of their food from a  distance.  Assume that the cost of raising that corn and bringing it to  the  town is

20s., and that the cost of raising it close to the town  is 15s. for every five bushels (we will suppose that in the

latter  instance the cost of carriage is nil); then, as both  quantities will  be sold at the same price, the surplus 5s.

In the  latter case will go  for rent. Thus we find that rent has arisen  because corn is brought  into the market at

different costs. In  twenty years more, rents will  have risen still further, because  soils still more inferior in

fertility or situation will have  been brought into cultivation. But  the rise of rent is not  directly due to the

cultivation of inferior  soils; the direct  cause is the increase of population which has made  that  cultivation

necessary. 

Going back to the question raised by Professor Rogers, as to  the  effect of agricultural improvements on rent,

we may notice  that the  controversy on this question was first fought out  between Ricardo and  Malthus.

Ricardo thought that improvements  would lead to a fall in  rents; Malthus maintained the opposite,  and he was

right. Take an acre  of land close to the town, such as  we were considering above, with an  original produce of

five  bushels of wheat, but which, under improved  cultivation, yields  forty bushels. If the price of wheat

remains the  same, and all  the land under cultivation has been improved to an  equivalent  extent, the rent will

now be 5s. multiplied by eight. Yet  there  are a few historical instances where agricultural improvements  have

been followed by a fall in rents. For instance, during the  Thirty Years' War the Swiss supplied Western

Germany with corn,  and  introduced improvements into their agriculture, in order to  meet the  pressure of the

demand. After the peace of Westphalia  the demand fell  off; the Swiss found they were producing more  than

they could sell;  prices fell, and, as a consequence, rents  fell also. 

Professor Rogers has further objected to Ricardo's theory  that it  does not explain the historical origin of rent.

The term  'rent' is  ambiguous; it has been used for the payment of  knightservice, for the  performances of

religious offices, for  serfs' labour and the sum of  money for which it was commuted. In  Ricardo's mouth it

meant only the  money rent paid by a capitalist  farmer, expecting the usual rates of  profits; but it is quite  true

that these modern competition rents did  not arise till about  the time of James I. 

The last point in the theory of rent is the relation between  rent  and price. Before Ricardo's time most practical

men thought  that rent  was a cause of price. Ricardo answered, There is land  cultivated in  England which pays

no rent, or at least there is  capital employed in  agriculture which pays none; therefore there  is in the market

corn  which has paid no rent, and it is the cost  of raising this corn, which  is grown on the poorest land, that

determines the price of all the  corn in the same market. Probably  he was right in his statement that  there is

land in England which  pays no rent; but even if all land and  all farmers' capital paid  rent, it would not affect

the argument,  which says that rent is  not the cause but the result of price. We may  conclude that at  the present

day rent is determined by two things: the  demand of  the population, and the quantity and quality of land

available.  These determine it by fixing the price of corn. 

Now let us turn to facts, to see how our theories work. We  will  take the rise in rents between 1790 and 1830,

and ask how it  came  about. The main causes were  (1) improvements in  agriculture, the  chief of which were

the destruction of the  commonfield system,  rendering possible the rotation of crops, the  consolidation of

farms  with the farmhouse in the centre of the  holding, and the introduction  of machinery and manures; (2) the

great growth of population,  stimulated by mechanical inventions;  (3) a series of bad harvests,  which raised

the price of corn to  an unparalleled height; (4) the  limitation of supply, the  population having to be fed with

the produce  of England itself,  since, during the first part of the period all  supplies from  abroad were cut off


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent 48



Top




Page No 51


by war, and later, higher and higher  protective duties were imposed, culminating in the famous corn  bill  of

1815. After 1815, however, a fall in rents  not a very  great  onetook place, a process which greatly puzzled

people at  the time. It  was the consequence of a sudden coincidence of  agricultural  improvements and good

harvests; there was for a time  an over  production of corn, and wheat fell in price from 90s. to  35s. This  fact is

the explanation of Ricardo's mistaken idea that  agricultural  improvements tend to reduce rents. Having no

historical turn of mind,  such as Malthus had, he did not  recognise that this effect of  agricultural

improvements was quite  accidental. This case, indeed, and  the instance of Switzerland  given above, with the

similar events in  Germany about 1820, are  the only historical examples of such an  effect. For a time there

was great agricultural distress; the farmers  could not get their  rents reduced in proportion to the fall in prices,

and many, in  spite of the enormous profits they had before made under  beneficial leases, were ruined; the

farming class never wholly  recovered till the repeal of the Corn Laws. But the fall was  temporary and

exceptional. Taking the period as a whole its  striking  feature is the rise of rents, and this rise was due to  the

causes  stated: increased demand on the part of an increased  population, and  limitation of quantity, with

improved quality, of  the land available. 

I have hitherto been considering the theory of agricultural  rents;  I now pass to a subject of perhaps greater

present  importance   groundrents in towns. If the rise in the rent of  agricultural lands  has been great, the

rise in that of urban  properties has been still  more striking. A house in Lombard  Street, the property of the

Drapers'  Company, was in 1668 let for  £25; in 1887 the site alone was let for  £2600. How do we account  for

this? It is the effect of the growth of  great towns and of  the improvements which enable greater wealth to be

produced in  them, owing to the development of the arts, and to the  extension  of banking and credit. Are town

rents then a cause of the  rise in  prices? Certainly not. Rent may be an element in price, but  the  actual amount

of rent paid depends upon these two things: the  demand of the population for commodities, which determines

price,  and  the value of a particular site for purposes of business. 

These considerations bring us to the question now sometimes  raised: is rent a thing which the State can

abolish? Is it a  human  institution, or the result of physical causes beyond our  control? If  we abolish

agricultural rent, the result would simply  be, as Ricardo  says, that the rent would go into the pockets of  the

farmers, and some  of them would live like gentlemen. Rent  itself is the result of  physical causes, but it is

within our  power to say who shall receive  the rent. This seems a fact of  immense importance, but the extent

of  its significance depends  largely on the future course of rent in  England; and so we are  bound to inquire

whether Ricardo was right in  assuming that rents  must necessarily rise in a progressing state. Many  think the

contrary, and that we are now on the eve of a certain and  permanent fall in agricultural rents; and if rents

continue  steadily  to fall, the question will become one of increasing  insignificance. As  means of

communication improve, we add more  and more to the supply of  land available for satisfying the wants  of a

particular place; and as  the supply increases, which it is  likely to do to an increasing  extent, the price of land

must  fall. Social causes have also  influenced rents in England, and  social changes are probably imminent,

which will at once reduce  the value of land for other than  agricultural purposes, and  increase the amount of it

devoted to  agriculture. Such changes  would likewise tend to diminish rent. We may  say therefore that,  since

there are these indications of a permanent  fall in rents,  so great a revolution as the transference of rent from

the hands  of private owners to the nation would not be justified by  the  amount which the nation would

acquire. The loss and damage of  such a revolution would not be adequately repaid. 

But will rent in towns fall? Here it is impossible to  predict. For  instance, we cannot say whether London will

continue  to grow as  rapidly as it has done heretofore. Now it is the  monetary centre of  the world; owing to the

greater use of  telegraphy, it is possible that  it may not retain this  preeminence. The decay of the provincial

towns  was largely due  to the growth of great estates, which enabled their  proprietors  to live and spend in

London; but if changes come to break  up  these large properties, London will cease to be the centre of  fashion,

or at any rate to have such a large fashionable  population.  Politics, moreover, are certainly tending to centre

less in London.  And further inventions in the means of locomotion  and the greater use  of electricity may

result in causing a  greater diffusion of  population. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent 49



Top




Page No 52


XIII. Two Theories of Economic Progress

Since Mill, in 1848, wrote his chapter on the future of the  working classes, the question of the distribution of

wealth has  become of still greater importance. We cannot look round on the  political phenomena of today

without seeing that this question  is at  the root of them. We see the perplexity in which men stand,  and the

divisions springing up in our great political parties,  because of the  uncertainty of politicians how to grapple

with it.  Political power is  now widely diffused; and whatever may be the  evils of democracy, this  good has

come of it, that it has forced  men to open their eyes to the  misery of the masses, and to  inquire more

zealously as to the  possibility of a better  distribution of wealth. Economists have to  answer the question

whether it is possible for the mass of the working  classes to  raise themselves under the present conditions of

competition and  private property. Ricardo and Henry George have both  answered,  No; and the former has

formulated a law of economic  development,  according to which, as we have seen, rent must rise,  profits and

interest fall, and wages remain stationary, or perhaps  fall. Now  is there any relation of cause and effect

between this rise  in  rent and fall in wages? Ricardo thought not. According to his  theory, profits and wages

are fixed independently of rent; a rise  in  rent and a fall in wages might be due to the same cause, but  the one

was not the result of the other, and the rise in rent  would not be at  the expense of the labourers. Yet practical

opinion goes in the  opposite direction. From the evidence of  farmers and landagents we  see that it is widely

believed that  the high rents exacted from  farmers have been partly taken out of  the pockets of the labourers.

'If there is a fall in the price of  corn, agricultural wages will  fall, unless there is a  corresponding fall in rent,'

was said before a  Parliamentary  Commission in 1834. Ten years ago the connection was  admitted in  Ireland;

and the Land Act of 1870 was founded on the  belief that  rackrents were not really the surplus left when

capital  and  labour had received their fair returns, and that the only limit  to the rise of rents was the bare

necessities of the peasantry.  In  England it has been assumed that wages and profits have fixed  lines of  their

own independent of rent, but this is not  universally true; where  the farmers have suffered from high  rents,

they in their turn have  ground down the labourers. Thus  even in England rent has been exacted  from the

labourer; and this  is not an opinion but a fact, testified by  the evidence of  agents, clergy, and farmers

themselves. What appears  accurate to  say about the matter is, that high rents have in some  cases been  one

cause of low wages. 

This direct effect of rent on wages under certain conditions  is  quite distinct from the 'brazen law of wages'

which Lassalle  took from  Ricardo. It is impossible, according to Ricardo, for  labourers to  improve their

position under existing industrial  conditions, for if  wages rise, population will advance also, and  wages return

to their  own level; there cannot therefore be any  permanent rise in them.  Ricardo, indeed, did not deny that

the  standard of comfort varied in  different countries, and in the  same country at different times; but  these

admissions he only  made parenthetically, he did not seem to  think they seriously  touched the question of

population, and they did  not affect his  main conclusions. For instance, he argues that a tax on  corn will  fall

entirely on profits, since the labourer is already  receiving  the lowest possible wages. This statement may be

true with  regard  to the very lowest class of labourers, but it certainly does  not  apply to artisans, nor to a large

proportion of English working  men at the present time. With them, at any rate, it is not true  that  they are

already receiving the lowest possible wage, nor  that there is  an invincible bar to their progress. Let us turn to

the test of facts  and see if wages have risen since 1846. Henry  George says that free  trade has done nothing

for the labourer'.  Mill, in 1848, predicted the  same. Professor Cairnes came to a  very similar conclusion;

writing in  1874 he said, that 'the large  addition to the wealth of the country  has gone neither to profit  nor to

wages, nor yet to the public at  large, but to swell... the  rentroll of the owner of the soil.' Yet it  is a fact that

though  the cost of living has undoubtedly increased,  wages have risen in  a higher ratio. Take the instance of a

carpenter  as a fair  average specimen of the artisan class. The necessaries of a  carpenter's family in 1839 cost

24s. 10d. per week; in 1875 they  cost  29s. But meanwhile the money wages of a carpenter had risen  from

24s.  to 35s. Thus there had been not only a nominal but a  real rise in his  wages. Turning to the labourer, his

cost of  living was about 15s. In  1839, it was a little under 15s. In  1875. The articles he consumes  have

decreased in cost, while in  the case of the artisan they have  increased, because the labourer  spends a much


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XIII. Two Theories of Economic Progress 50



Top




Page No 53


larger proportion of his  wages on bread. The  labourer's wages meanwhile have risen from 8s. to  12s. or 14s.;

in 1839 he could not properly support himself on his  wages alone.  These facts seem conclusive, but certainty

is difficult  from the  very varying estimates of consumption and money wages. For  strong  proof of a rise in

agricultural wages we may take a particular  instance. On an estate in Forfar the yearly wages of a first

ploughman were by the wagesbook, in 

1840... £28  2 0       1870... £42 5 0

1850...  28 15 0       1880...  48 9 0

1860...  39  7 0

According to his own admission the standard of comfort of the  first  ploughman employed on this estate in

1810 had risen, for he  complained, in a letter describing his position, of his increased  expenditure, increased

not because things were dearer, but  because he  now needed more of them. 

We may take as further evidence the statistics of the savings  of  the working classes; it is impossible to get

more than an  approximate  estimate of them, but they probably amount to about  £130,000,000. To  these we

may add the savings actually invested  in houses. In  Birmingham there are 13,000 houses owned by  artisans.

All this is  small compared with the whole capital of  the country, which, in 1875,  was estimated at

£8,500,000,000 at  least, with an annual increase of  £235,000,000  this latter sum  far exceeding the total

savings of the  working classes. The  comparison will make us take a sober view of  their improvement;  yet the

facts make it clear that the working  classes can raise  their position, though not in the same ratio as the  middle

classes. Mr Mulhall also estimates that there is less  inequality  between the two classes now than forty years

ago. He  calculates  that the average wealth of a rich family has decreased from  £28,820 to £25,803, or 11 per

cent.; that of a middleclass  family  has decreased from £1439 to £1005, or 30 per cent.; while  that of a

workingclass family has increased from £44 to £86, or  nearly 100 per  cent. But without pinning our faith to

any  particular estimate, we can  see clearly enough that the facts  disprove Ricardo's proposition that  no

improvement is possible;  and there are not wanting some who think  that the whole tendency  of modern

society is towards an increasing  equality of condition. 

Was Ricardo any more correct in saying that interest and  profits  (between which he never clearly

distinguished) must fall?  As a matter  of fact, for the last century and a half interest in  England has been

almost stationary, except during the great war.  In Walpole's time it  was three per cent.; during the war it

doubled, but after the peace it  dropped to four per cent., and  has remained pretty steady at that rate  ever since.

Ricardo  thought that the cost of the labourer's  subsistence would  necessarily increase, owing to the necessity

of  cultivating more  land, and as he would thus require a greater share of  the gross  produce, less wealth would

be left for the capitalist. He  overlooked the fact that the rate of interest depends not merely  on  the cost of

labour, but on the field of employment as well. As  civilisation advances, new inventions and new enterprises

create  a  fresh demand for capital: some £700,000,000 have been invested  in  English railways alone. No

doubt, if the field for English  capital  were confined to England, the rate of interest might  fall; but Ricardo

forgot the possibility of capital emigrating on  a large scale. Thus  Ricardo's teaching on this point is deficient

both in abstract theory  and as tested by facts. What we really  find to have taken place is,  that though rent has

risen, there is  good reason to suppose that in  the future it may fall; that  interest has not fallen much; and that

the standard of comfort  and the rate of wages, both of artisans and  labourersof the  former most decidedly,

and to a certain extent also  of the  latter, has risen. 

I wish next to examine Mr George's theory of economic  progress. Mr  George is a disciple of Ricardo, both in

his method  and his  conclusions; he has as great a contempt for facts and  verification as  Ricardo himself. By

this method he succeeds in  formulating a law,  according to which, in the progress of  civilisation, interest and

wages will fall together, and rents  will rise. Not only is the  labourer in a hopeless condition, but  the capitalist

is equally doomed  to a stationary or declining  fortune. 'Rent,' he says, 'depends upon  the margin of

cultivation, rising as it falls, and falling as it  rises.  Interest and wages depend on the margin of cultivation,


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XIII. Two Theories of Economic Progress 51



Top




Page No 54


falling  as it falls, and rising as it rises.' The returns which the  capitalist obtains for his capital and the labourer

for his work  depend on the returns from the worst land cultivated; that is, on  the  quality of land accessible to

capital and labour without  payment of  rent. 

Now Mr George's observations are derived from America, and  what he  has done is to generalise a theory,

which is true of some  parts of  America, but not of old countries. His book seems  conclusive enough at  first

sight. There is little flaw in the  reasoning, if we grant the  premisses; but there are great flaws  in the results

when tested by  facts. Do interest and wages always  rise and fall together? As an  historical fact they do not.

Between 1715 and 1760, while rents  (according to Professor  Rogers) rose but slowly (Arthur Young denies

that they rose at  all), interest fell, and wages rose. Between 1790  and 1815 rent  doubled, interest doubled,

wages fell. Between 1846 and  1882  rents have risen, interest has been stationary, wages have risen.  Thus in

all these three periods the facts contradict Mr George's  theory. Rent indeed has generally risen, but neither

profits nor  wages have steadily fallen, nor have their variations borne any  constant relation to one another.

Coming to Mr George's main  position, that rent constantly tends to absorb the whole increase  of  national

wealth, how does this look in the light of fact? Does  all the  increase of wealth, for instance, in the Lancashire

cotton  manufactures, go simply to raise rents? Evidently not.  Wages have  risen owing to improvements in

machinery'. and in most  cases profits  have also risen. We can prove by statistics that in  England the

capitalists' wealth has increased faster than that of  the landowners".  for in the assessments to the incometax

there  has been a greater  increase under Schedule D, which comprises the  profits of capitalists  and the

earnings of professional men, than  under Schedule A, which  comprises revenues from land. At the same  time,

Mr George has made out  a strong case against private  property in land in great towns; but  here he has only

restated  more forcibly what Adam Smith and Mill  advocated, when they  recommended taxes on ground rents

as the least  objectionable of  all taxes. Under existing conditions the working  people in great  towns may be

said to be taxed in the worst of ways by  the bad  condition of their houses. An individual or a corporation lets

a  block of buildings for a term of years; the lessee sublets it,  and  the sublessee again for the third time. Each

class is here  oppressing  the one beneath it, and the lowest unit suffers most.  This is why the  problem of the

distribution of wealth is sure, in  the near future, to  take the form of the question, how to house  the labourers

of our  towns. 

XIV. The Future of the Working Classes

I have thus far tried to show that the material condition of  the  workman is capable of improvement under

present social  conditions. I  wish now to explain the causes which have  contributed to its actual  improvement

since 1846. The most  prominent of these causes has been  Free Trade. In the first  place, Free Trade has

enormously increased  the aggregate wealth  of the country, and therefore increased the  demand for labour;

this is an indisputable fact. Secondly, it has  created greater  steadiness in trade,a point which is often

overlooked  in  discussions of the subject. Since 1846 workmen have been more  regularly employed than in

the preceding halfcentury. Free trade  in  wheat has, moreover, given us a more steady price of bread, a  point

of  paramount importance to the labouring man; and this  steadiness is  continually becoming greater. From

1850 to 1860 the  variation between  the highest and lowest prices of wheat was  36s., between 1860 and 1870

it was 24s., and in the last decade  it has been only 15s. And since  the sum which the workman has  spent on

bread has become more and more  constant, the amount  which he has had left to spend on manufactured

produce has also  varied less, and its price in consequence has been  steadier. But  why then, it may be asked,

the late great depression of  trade  since 1877? I believe the answer is, because other countries, to  which we

sell our goods, have been suffering from bad harvests,  and  have had less capacity for buying. The weavers in

Lancashire  have had  to work less time and at lower wages because faroff  nations have not  been able to

purchase cotton goods, and the  depression in one industry  has spread to other branches of trade. 

The greater steadiness of wages which has been caused by Free  Trade is seen even in trades where there has

been no great rise.  But  besides the amount of the workman's wages per day we must  take into  consideration


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XIV. The Future of the Working Classes 52



Top




Page No 55


the number of days in the year and hours  in the day,  during which he works. He now finds employment on

many more days  (before 1846 artisans often worked only one or two  days in the week),  but each working day

has fewer hours; so that  his pay is at once  steadier and more easily earned. And hence  even where his daily

wages  have remained nearly the same, with  more constant employment and with  bread both cheap and fixed

in  price, his general position has  improved. 

What other agencies besides Free Trade have been at work to  bring  about this improvement? Factory

legislation has raised the  condition  of women and children by imposing a limit on the hours  of work, and

especially the sanitary environment of the labourer;  the factory laws  seek to regulate the whole life of the

workshop.  TradesUnions, again,  have done much to avert social and  industrial disorder, and have  taught

workmen, by organisation and  selfhelp, to rely upon  themselves. Herein lies the difference  between the

English and the  Continental workman; the former,  because he has been free from  voluntary associations, does

not  look to the State or to revolutionary  measures to better his  position. For proof of this, it is enough to

compare the  parliamentary programme of the last TradesUnions Congress  with  the proceedings of the

international at Geneva. English  TradesUnions resort to a constitutional agitation which involves  no  danger

to the State; indeed, as I have said, their action  averts  violent industrial dislocations. And beyond this,

TradesUnions have  achieved some positive successes for the cause  of labour. By means of  their

accumulated funds workmen have been  able to hold out for better  prices for their labour, and the  Unions have

further acted as  provident societies by means of  which their members can lay up sums  against sickness or old

age.  The mischief and wastefulness of strikes  is generally enough  insisted on, but it is not as often

remembered  that the largest  Unions have sanctioned the fewest strikes; the  Amalgamated  Engineers, who

have 46,000 members, and branches in Canada  and  India, expended only six per cent. of their income on

strikes  from 1867 to 1877. The leaders of such a great Union are skilful,  wellinformed men, who know it to

be in their interest to avoid  strikes. 

Lastly, we must not forget to mention the great Cooperative  Societies, which in their modern shape date

from the Rochdale  Pioneers' Store, founded in 1844, under the inspiration of Robert  Owen's teaching, though

the details of his plan were therein  abandoned. These, like TradesUnions, have taught the power and  merit

of voluntary association and selfhelp. At present,  however, they are  only big shops for the sale of retail

goods,  through which the workman  gets rid of the retail dealer, and  shares himself in the profits of  the

business, by receiving at  the end of each quarter a dividend on  his purchases. Such stores,  however useful in

cheapening goods, and at  the same time  encouraging thrift, do not represent the ultimate object  of

cooperation. That object is to make the workman his own  employer.  Hitherto the movement has not been

successful in  establishing  productive societies; the two great difficulties in  the way being  apparently the

inability of a committee of workmen  to manage a  business well, and their unwillingness to pay  sufficiently

high wages  for superintendence. The chief obstacles  are thus moral, and to be  found in the character of the

workmen,  and their want of education;  but as their character and education  improve, there is no reason why

these difficulties should not  vanish. 

Such are the chief agencies to which we trace the improvement  in  the position of the labourer during the last

forty years. At  the  beginning of this period Mill insisted on one thing as of  paramount  importance, namely

restriction upon the increase of  population, and  without this he believed all improvement to be  impossible.

Yet we find  that during this period the rate of  increase has not slackened. It is  nearly as great now as between

1831 and 1841. It was greater during  the last decade than it had  been since 1841. On the other hand, there  has

undoubtedly been an  enormous emigration which has lightened the  supply of labour.  Three millions and a

half of people have emigrated  from Great  Britain since 1846. 

The question which now most deeply concerns us is, Will the  same  causes operate in the future? Will Free

Trade continue to be  beneficial? Will our wealth continue to increase and our trade to  expand? On this point a

decided prediction is of course  impossible.  Competition in neutral markets is becoming keener and  keener,

and we  may be driven out of some of them, and thus the  national aggregate of  wealth be lessened. But, on the


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XIV. The Future of the Working Classes 53



Top




Page No 56


other hand,  we have reason to believe  that increased supplies of corn from  America and Australia will give  an

enormous impetus to trade. As  in the past so in the future corn is  the commodity of most  importance to the

labourer; and if the supply of  corn becomes  more constant, trade will be steadier and wages will  probably

rise. Besides, cheap corn means that all over the world the  purchasing power of consumers is increased, and

this again will  stimulate trade. So that in this respect the labourers' outlook  is a  hopeful one. As to emigration

also, there is no reason to  suppose that  there will be any check on this relief to the  labourer for the next  fifty

years at least. Again, there is every  prospect of cooperation  and even productive cooperation making  great

progress in the future,  though I do not think that the  latter is likely for some time to be an  important factor in

improving the status of the workmen. The moral  obstacles to  cooperative production which I mentioned will

disappear  but  slowly. In certain directions, however, it is likely to develop;  I mean in the direction of

manufacturing for the great Wholesale  Cooperative Societies, because here the market is secured.

TradesUnions too are likely to expand. 

Turning to the moral condition of the workpeople, we find an  improvement greater even than their material

progress. When we  see or  read of what goes on in the streets of our great towns, we  think badly  enough of

their morality; but those who have had most  experience in  manufacturing districts are of opinion that the

moral advance, as  manifested, for example, in temperance, in  orderly behaviour, in  personal appearance, in

dress, has been  very great. For the  improvement in the inner life of workshops as  early as 1834, take the

evidence of Francis Place, a friend of  James Mill, before a Committee  of the House of Commons in that  year.

He told the Committee that, when  he was a boy, he used to  hear songs, such as he could not repeat, sung  in

respectable  shops by respectable people; it was so no longer, and  he was at a  loss how to account for the

change. Similar statements are  made  by workmen at the present day. Conversation, they say, is bad at  times,

but opinion is setting more and more against immoral talk.  The  number of subjects which interest workpeople

is much greater  than  before, and the discussion of the newspaper is supplanting  the old  foul language of the

workshop. We have here an indirect  effect of the  extension of the suffrage. Add to this the  statistics of

drunkenness.  In 1855 there were nearly 20,000  persons convicted for drunkenness, in  1880 there were not

many  more than 11,000. 

Again, the relations between workmen and employers are  certainly  much better. The old life, as described by

Owen and  Cobbett, of an  apprentice in the workshop, or a boarded labourer  in the farmhouse, is  at first sight

most attractive; and the  facts told to the Commission  of 1806 seem to realise the ideal  life of industry. The

relations  between masters and workmen were  then extremely close, but this close  relationship had its bad

side. There was often great brutality and  gross vice. The workman  was at his employer's mercy. In Norfolk

the  farmer used to  horsewhip his labouring men, and his wife the women.  There  existed a state of feudal

dependence, which, like all feudalism,  had its dark and light sides. The close relationship was  distinctly  the

result of the small system of industry, and hence  it was shattered  by the powerloom and the steamengine.

When  huge factories were  established there could no longer be a close  tie between the master  and his men;

the workman hated his  employer, and the employer looked  on his workmen simply as hands.  From 1800 to

1843 their mutual  relations, as was admitted by both  parties, were as bad as they could  be. There could be no

union,  said employers, between classes whose  interests were different,  and farmers, contrary to ancient usage,

ruthlessly turned off  their men when work was slack. The 'cash nexus'  had come in, to  protest against which

Carlyle wrote his Past and  Present; but  Carlyle was wrong in supposing that the old conditions of  labour

could be reestablished. Feudalism, though it lingers in a few  country places, has virtually disappeared alike

in agriculture  and in  trade. The employer cannot offer and the workman cannot  accept the old  relations of

protection and dependence: for, owing  to the modern  necessity of the constant movement of labour from

place to place and  from one employment to another, it has become  impossible to form  lasting relations, and

the essence of the old  system lay in the  permanency of the workmen's engagements.  TradesUnions too have

done  much to sever what was left of the  old ties. Workmen are now obliged,  in selfdefence, to act in  bodies.

In every workshop there are men who  are attached to their  masters, and who on occasion of a strike do not

care to come out,  but are yet compelled to do so in the common  interest. Before  this obligation was

recognised by public opinion, the  effect of  Unions was, no doubt, to embitter the relations between  masters


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XIV. The Future of the Working Classes 54



Top




Page No 57


and men. This was especially the case between 1840 and 1860. 

Since the latter date, however, TradesUnions have distinctly  improved the relations between the two classes.

Employers are  beginning to recognise the necessity of them, and the advantages  of  being able to treat with a

whole body of workmen through their  most  intelligent members. Boards of Conciliation, in which  workmen

and  employers sit side by side, would be impossible  without Unions to  enforce obedience to their decisions.

In the  north of England, at the  present moment, it is the nonunionists  who are rejecting arbitration.  And the

reason why such Boards  have succeeded is, because the  employers have of their own accord  abandoned all

ideas of the feudal  relation. They used to say that  it would degrade them to sit at the  same board with their

workmen; but it is noticeable that directly the  political  independence of the latter was recognised, as soon as

he  possessed the franchise, these objections began to disappear. The  new  union of employers and workmen

which is springing up in this  way, is  based on the independence of both as citizens of a free  state. The

employers meet their workmen also in political  committees, on School  Boards and similar bodies, and the

two  classes are learning to respect  one another. Thus this new union  bids fair to be stronger than the old  one. 

Still the question remains, Can this political independence  of the  workman be combined with secure material

independence?  Until this is  done he will be always at the mercy of his  employer, who may  practically stultify

his political power by  influencing his vote, as  Mr George asserts is done in New  England. Among the many

solutions of  this problem proposed in our  own country two deserve especial  prominence. The first is that of

the English Positivists. Comte,  although he had but a glimpse of  the English TradesUnions, understood  the

meaning of them far  better than Mill. Inspired by him, Mr Frederic  Harrison and his  friends deny the

possibility of solving the labour  question by  cooperative production or any such schemes. They rely on  a

gradual change in the moral nature of capitalists; not that they  expect the old system of feudal protection to

return, but they  hope  that the 'captains of industry' of the future will rise to  another  conception of their

position, will recognise the  independence of the  workman, and at the same time be willing to  hand over to

him an  increased share of their joint produce. This  belief may seem  ridiculous, and we must expect for a long

time  yet to see capitalists  still striving to obtain the highest  possible profits. But observe,  that the passion for

wealth is  certainly in some senses new. It grew  up very rapidly at the  beginning of the present century; it was

not so  strong in the  last century, when men were much more content to lead a  quiet  easy life of leisure. The

change has really influenced the  relations between men; but in the future it is quite possible  that  the scramble

for wealth may grow less intense, and a change  in the  opposite direction take place. The Comtists are right

when  they say  that men's moral ideas are not fixed. The attitude of  public opinion  towards slavery was

completely changed in twenty  or thirty years.  Still I am obliged to believe that such a moral  revolution as the

Comtists hope for is not possible within a  reasonable space of time. 

I should have more hope of industrial Partnership as  elaborately  described by Mr Sedley Taylor. This also

implies a  certain change in  the moral nature of the employers, but one not  so great as the  alternative system

would require. It has been  adopted in over a  hundred Continental workshops, though the  experiment of

Messrs Briggs  in England ended in failure. There is  hope of its being more  successful in the future, because

by  promoting the energy of the  workmen and diminishing waste, it  coincides with the interest of the

employer. I think that in some  industries it will extend, but that it  will not be generally  adopted. 

There remains the ordinary Communist solution. This has taken  various forms; the simplest being a voluntary

association of  individuals based on the principle of common property, and in  which  every person works for

the community according to fixed  rules. There  are many successful instances of this, on a small  scale, in the

United  States, but we cannot suppose such a  solution to be possible for  society as a whole. It has only been

tried with picked materials,  whereas our object is rather to  improve the great mass of the  population. The

Communism of recent  European theorists, of whom the  best known is Lassalle, presents  a somewhat different

aspect. It aims  at the appropriation of all  instruments of production by the State,  which is to take charge  of the

whole national industry and direct it.  But the practical  difficulty of such a scheme is obviously

overwhelming. The  objections to a Communistic solution do not apply to  Socialism in  a more modified


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XIV. The Future of the Working Classes 55



Top




Page No 58


shape. Historically speaking, Socialism  has  already shown itself in England in the extension of State

interference. It has produced the Factory Laws, and it is now  beginning to advance further and interfere

directly in the  division  of produce between the workmen and their employers. The  Employers'  Liability Act

recognises that workmen, even when  associated in  TradesUnions, cannot without other aid secure full

justice, and in  the name of justice it has distinctly handed over  to the workmen a  certain portion of the

employers' wealth. The  extension of relative  interference however, though it is to be  expected in one or two

directions, is not likely to be of much  further importance. With  regard to taxation, on the other hand,  Socialist

principles will  probably attain a widereaching  application, and here we shall see  great changes. 

The readjustment of taxation would enable the State to supply  for  the people many things which they cannot

supply for  themselves.  Without assuming the charge of every kind of  production, the State  might take into its

hands such businesses  of vital importance as  railways, or the supply of gas and water.  And should not the

State  attempt in the future to grapple with  such questions as the housing of  the labourers? Municipalities

might be empowered to buy ground and let  it for building purposes  below the full competition market value. I

think that such a  scheme is practicable without demoralising the  people, and it  would attack a problem which

has hitherto baffled every  form of  private enterprise; for all the Societies put together, which  have been

formed in London with this object since 1842, have  succeeded in housing only 60,000 persons. And this

brings up the  whole question of public expenditure for the people. A new form  of  association, which has

become common of late years, is that of  a  certain number of private individuals combining to provide for

some  want of the public, such as Coffee Taverns, or Artisans'  Dwellings, or  cheap music. Such Societies are

founded primarily  with philanthropic  objects, but they also aim at a fair interest  on their capital. Might  not

municipalities seek in a similar way  to provide for the poor? In  discussing all such schemes, however,  we

must remember that the real  problem is not how to produce some  improvement in the condition of the

working man  for that has to  a certain extent been attained already   but how to secure his  complete material

independence. 


Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England

XIV. The Future of the Working Classes 56



Top





Bookmarks



1. Table of Contents, page = 3

2. Lectures on The Industrial Revolution in England, page = 4

   3. Arnold Toynbee, page = 4

   4. I Introductory, page = 4

   5. II. England in 1760, page = 6

   6. III England in 1760, page = 10

   7. IV England in 1760, page = 13

   8. V. England in 1760, page = 18

   9. VI. England in 1760, page = 22

   10. VII. The Mercantile System and Adam Smith, page = 24

   11. VIII. The Chief Features of the Revolution, page = 30

   12. IX. The Growth of Pauperism, page = 34

   13. X. Malthus and the Law of Population, page = 39

   14. XI. The Wage-Fund Theory, page = 43

   15. XII. Ricardo and the Growth of Rent, page = 48

   16. XIII. Two Theories of Economic Progress, page = 53

   17. XIV. The Future of the Working Classes, page = 55